Agency problem: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Line 7: Line 7:
But the [[iterated prisoner’s dilemma]] has a couple of natural limits: One is that it relies on repeated interactions with an indeterminate end-point: the promise of another opportunity, on another day, to clip your ticket. When the sky is falling on your head, it looks like a final interaction, and the calculus is different.  
But the [[iterated prisoner’s dilemma]] has a couple of natural limits: One is that it relies on repeated interactions with an indeterminate end-point: the promise of another opportunity, on another day, to clip your ticket. When the sky is falling on your head, it looks like a final interaction, and the calculus is different.  


Second, it takes no account of “[[convexity]]” effects: I can build up my reputation incrementally by faithfully carrying out thousands of small transactions — I can ''look'' like a five-star collaborator — only to blow it on one big position. I can sell ten thousand ball point pens in utter good faith and welch the one time I sell a Ferrari.  
Second, it takes no account of “[[convexity]]” effects: I can build up my reputation incrementally by faithfully carrying out thousands of small transactions — I can ''look'' like a consistent five-star collaborator — only to blow it on one big position. I can sell ten thousand ball point pens in utmost good faith and rub off with your money the one time I purport to sell a Ferrari.  


When that one outsized reward more than compensates for all the thousands of pennies in front of the steamroller, the normal rules don’t apply and an iterated game of prisoner’s dilemma becomes a one-off. This is what {{author|Nassim Nicholas Taleb}} calls the “Rubin Trade”.
When that one outsized “defection” reward more than compensates for all the thousands of pennies in front of the steamroller, the normal rules don’t apply and an iterated game of prisoner’s dilemma effectively becomes a [[single round prisoner’s dilemma|single round]] game, for which the option payoff is markedly different. This is what {{author|Nassim Nicholas Taleb}} calls the “Rubin Trade”.


Thus, the agency problem is the classic “[[skin in the game]]” problem: an agent gets paid, no matter what. The [[investment manager]] puts no capital up, takes a small slice of ''yours'', by way of a fee, no matter what.  
Thus, the agency problem is the classic “[[skin in the game]]” problem: an agent gets paid, no matter what. The [[investment manager]] puts no capital up, takes a small slice of ''yours'', by way of a fee, no matter what.  
Line 24: Line 24:
So do ''all'' its agents have such a common conflicting interest? ''Yes''.  
So do ''all'' its agents have such a common conflicting interest? ''Yes''.  


Any one of its agents is charged with protecting the principal’s interests, but two overriding considerations will inevitably take priority: (i) their wish to protect and perpetuate their own role ''as'' agent, and protect its accompanying income stream — their need to ''persuade the principal that their role is needed'' whether or not it ''is'' needed — no turkey votes for Christmas; and (ii) their wish to not ''fuck up'' — not only is the role necessary but ''I am a suitable person to carry out that role''.  
Any one of its agents is charged with protecting the principal’s interests, but two overriding considerations will inevitably take priority: (i) their wish to protect and perpetuate their own role ''as'' agent, and its accompanying income stream — their need to ''persuade the principal that their role is needed'' whether or not it ''is'' needed — no turkey votes for Christmas; and (ii) their wish to not ''fuck up'' — to demonstrate that not only is the role necessary but ''I am the best person to carry out that role''.  
===Legal industry transformation and the agency problem===
===Legal industry transformation and the agency problem===
The JC humbly submits that any plan to revolutionise the legal industry that does not account for the [[agency problem]] ''will fail''. Everyone who purports to speak for a corporation does so in a way that, above all else, does not prejudice {{sex|his}} own agency with the corporation.
The JC humbly submits that any plan to revolutionise the legal industry that does not account for the [[agency problem]] ''will fail''.  


This puts our old friend the [[drills and holes]] conundrum into perspective: it is true that a corporation desires quick, cheap and effective legal services. In many cases, it does not need ''any'' legal services ''at all'' — it could do not just with legal protections delivered in a convenient format and by a less expensive source, but ''no legal protections at all''. What percentage of legal agreements are ever litigated? But it is hard for an inanimate pile of papers filed at companies registry to have that sort of insight. It relies on its agents to arrive at that conclusion on its behalf. But who, amongst the byzantine control structure that those very agents have constructed to help it make decisions of that sort — its [[inhouse counsel]], [[outhouse counsel]], credit risk management, document [[negotiators]], client [[onboarding]] team, [[compliance]] or [[internal audit]] — who of these people would ever say that? And even if one did, would {{sex|he}} not be shut down by the consensus of the others?<ref>Those who don’t believe me should try proposing that you don’t need [[cross default]] in trading agreements. You will get bilateral consensus on this, in private conversations, from almost everyone; no-one will say it in public.</ref>
Everyone who purports to speak for a corporation does so in a way that, above all else, does not prejudice {{sex|his}} own agency with the corporation.
 
This puts our old friend the [[drills and holes]] conundrum into perspective: it is true that a corporation desires quick, cheap and effective legal services. In many cases, it does not need ''any'' legal services ''at all'' — it could get by not just with cheaper, less fulsome legal protections, but with ''no legal protections at all''. What percentage of legal agreements are ever litigated?  
 
But it is hard for an inanimate pile of papers filed at companies registry to have that sort of insight. It relies on its ''agents'' to arrive at that conclusion on its behalf. But who, amongst the byzantine control structure that those very agents have constructed to help it make decisions of that sort — its [[inhouse counsel]], [[outhouse counsel]], credit risk management, document [[negotiators]], client [[onboarding]] team, [[compliance]] or [[internal audit]] — who of these people would ever say that? And even if one did, would {{sex|he}} not be shut down by the consensus of the others?<ref>Those who don’t believe me should try proposing that you don’t need [[cross default]] in trading agreements. You will get bilateral consensus on this, in private conversations, from almost everyone; no-one will say it in public.</ref>


===Big law and the agency problem===
===Big law and the agency problem===
Line 46: Line 50:
The business of advising on [[mergers and acquisitions]] and primary transactions in the [[debt capital markets|debt]] and [[equity capital markets]] is generally handled on behalf of target and acquiror by appointed [[investment banks]].  
The business of advising on [[mergers and acquisitions]] and primary transactions in the [[debt capital markets|debt]] and [[equity capital markets]] is generally handled on behalf of target and acquiror by appointed [[investment banks]].  


Each bank will appoint it's own law firm to advise ''it'' — the target will have its own independent counsel too — principally on the underwriting, regulatory and reputational risks posed by being involved in the proposed transaction. The bank’s legal advisors will conduct due diligence, negotiate contracts, shareholders agreements, draft prospectuses, advise on all kinds of competition issues that may arise, and will issue batteries of [[legal opinion]]s — enforceability opinions, [[true sale opinion]]s, fairness opinions, security opinions, [[10b5 opinion]]s — you name it — all of which are designed to give the [[arranger]] and syndicates — the ''banks'' — comfort that ''their'' risk of shareholder action or regulatory censor is minimal. Who pays for all this legal advice? The bank’s ''client'', of course. This, on top of the underwriting fee, will be in the first blushing exchanges of the [[engagement letter]].
Each bank will appoint its own law firm to advise ''it'' — the target will have its own independent counsel too — principally on the underwriting, regulatory and reputational risks posed by just being involved. The bank’s legal advisors will conduct due diligence, negotiate contracts, shareholders agreements, draft prospectuses, advise on all kinds of competition issues that may arise, and will issue batteries of [[legal opinion]]s — enforceability opinions, [[true sale opinion]]s, fairness opinions, security opinions, [[10b5 opinion]]s — you name it — all of which are designed to give the [[arranger]] and syndicates — the ''banks'' — comfort that ''their'' risk of shareholder action or regulatory censure is minimal. Who pays for all this legal advice? The bank’s ''client'', of course. This, on top of the underwriting fee, will be in the first blushing exchanges of the [[engagement letter]].


Once the client has agreed to this — and, for the most part, clients have no choice — the bank’s internal lawyers have little incentive, beyond basic compassion for defenceless multinationals, to constrain their legal spend, and will allow themselves to be led down every open manhole cover that any deal lawyer can contrive to fall into.  
Once the client has agreed to this — and, for the most part, clients have no choice — the bank’s internal lawyers have little incentive, beyond basic compassion for defenceless multinationals, to constrain their legal spend, and will allow themselves to be led down every open manhole cover that any deal lawyer can contrive to fall into.  


Inhouse advisory teams are likely exempt from the usual rubber glove inspection — competitive tenders, law firm panels, methodological justifications —that follow requests from other parts of the legal department to incur “own legal spend”, even in nugatory amounts.
Inhouse advisory teams are often exempt, what’s more, from the usual internal audit rubber glove inspection — requiring competitive tenders, law firm panels, methodological justifications for even talking to lawyers — that follow requests from other parts of the legal department to incur “own legal spend”, even in nugatory amounts, because “the bank isn’t paying for it, so why get bent out of shape about it?”


====[[Litigation]]====
====[[Litigation]]====