Antitrust: Difference between revisions

4,186 bytes added ,  16 March 2023
no edit summary
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 2: Line 2:
It is through the offices of antitrust law that your plan to meet your buddy from Morgan Stanley for lunch, attend an industry round-table about Phase 5 Margin protocols will send your compliance department into high orbit. It is the [[legal eagle]]’s worst nightmare — that an innocent conversation about something sensible will see you both sent to jail.
It is through the offices of antitrust law that your plan to meet your buddy from Morgan Stanley for lunch, attend an industry round-table about Phase 5 Margin protocols will send your compliance department into high orbit. It is the [[legal eagle]]’s worst nightmare — that an innocent conversation about something sensible will see you both sent to jail.


This is normally harmless nest-feathering of course, and simply allows parasitic law firms to nuzzle away at the collective arteries of the financial system in how they write [[Netting opinion|netting opinions]] unbothered by earnest attempts to force them into some kind of consistency, but occasionally, as in the [[Archegos]] situation, the paranoid fear of one kind of opprobrium — being told off for collaborating in an anticompetitive way —can lead to the very real prospect of another — losing, between you, 10 billion dolllars.
This is normally harmless nest-feathering of course, and simply allows parasitic law firms to nuzzle away at the collective arteries of the financial system in how they write [[Netting opinion|netting opinions]] unbothered by earnest attempts to force them into some kind of consistency, but occasionally, as in the [[Archegos]] situation, the paranoid fear of one kind of opprobrium — being told off for collaborating in an anticompetitive way —can lead to the very real prospect of another — losing, between you, 10 billion dollars.
 
But here’s the funny thing. We fear the shadow of the antitrust reaper — and the odd careless executive might get thrown in jail for some small collusion — but on the grand scale, in terms of policing the basic thing antitrust is meant to stop — businesses acquiring and then exploiting [[dominant position|dominant positions in the market]] — the antitrust authorities are absent without official leave.
 
Consider: the Sherman Act led, eventually, to the splitting up of Standard Oil, American Tobacco; United States Steel; Aluminum Company of America; International Harvester; National Cash Register; Westinghouse; General Electric; Kodak; Dupont; Union Pacific railroad; and Southern Pacific railroad and finally the Bell telephone system.
 
Few of these businesses had the sort of reach and dominance of Alphabet, Amazon, Facebook, Apple, Meta, yet we hear little from the regulators — some noise from the EU, almost none from the Americans.
 
Those in the know will say, well, you see, it is all about whether the retail customer is hurt. Standard Oil gouged working class stiffs with its prices at the pump. But do you see the retail customers complaining about Apple, Google and Amazon? Facebook is free, for crying out loud!
 
This is, we think, to apply a narrow lens. The question here is about the orderly operation of markets, and a key component of that is ''[[scale]]''.
 
The fatal flaw in ultra-free market capitalism — is its predication on perfect information and perfect opportunity to compete, which implies none of the participants have a material, inherent, advantage over the others. Scale gives exactly such a material, inherent advantage. Therefore a “perfect free market environment” is ''not'' a stable equilibrium. As it operates, the more successful participants will get bigger, and acquire economies of scale. As they get bigger, they become more effective competitors, meaning they win even more market share, meaning they get bigger still.
 
Now, until about 1980, there were limits to the economy of scale: there is a point where the internal organisation itself gets so unwieldy, and irrevocably committed to a single business model, that it can’t innovate, or react to smaller competitors who do. You create supply chains, branch networks, warehouses, and so on. These have a drag on your profitability, and are increasingly difficult to change should the market change. So the “scale effect” wears off and ultimately can go negative: the bigger you are the worse a competitor you are.
 
But starting in the 1980s two things happened: Firstly the privatisation ideology took hold of the private sector: In the same way that governments were getting out of non-core activities like running railway lines and coal mines, so did corporates get out of non-core activities: whole divisions were outsourced, off-shorted, or de-merged, giving the core business back a lot of flexibility it had lost. If it no longer makes sense to manufacture a given product or component, just terminate the contract with the supplier and move on. No commitment.
 
Secondly, the internet arrived. Suddenly businesses found they were automatically connected with their customers, suppliers and markets and no-longer needed their own network infrastructure to reach their clients. Clients came to them. Again, some of the inhibitors and breaks on the economy of scale were removed.
 
Sleeping giant organisations lost out to scrappy start-ups like Amazon: Barnes & Noble, Sears & Roebuck, even IBM. But suddenly the startups themselves were behemoths, their lack of infrastructure meant they could beat out the giants.
 
Suddenly, scale was much less of a limiting factor, because so much of it could be achieved with software.
 
A similar thing was happening in banking. Banks started scaling back branches, and reaching customers electronically. Previously, banks had grown (like Citi) through acquisition. Now not just the regulatory barrier to entry but  a scale one. As we rolled into the 2000s we became aware of a bigger Most investment banks are well and truly past that point.
 
nor for that matter Vanguard, Blackrock, Goldman, Citigroup, PIMCO
 
{{ref}}
{{ref}}