First law of worker entropy: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|work|}}{{first law of worker entropy}}
{{a|work|{{image|angels meeting|jpg|''I Meet To Make You, But To Destroy Me'', {{vsr|1916}} }}}}{{first law of worker entropy}}


This is because the distribution of arrival times to the meeting is asymmetrically distributed at or past the scheduled start time. No one<ref>Outside the German-speaking countries: Peculiar cultural factors (particularly ''[[späteankunftschande]]'' and ''[[früheankunftfreude]]'') are at work here which can skew the calculation, but do not displace the general thrust of the theory.</ref> arrives early, some people arrive late, and experienced meeting participants know of this asymmetric distribution and therefore time their own arrival to the expected functional starting time of the meeting, which in turn further retards that average start time.  
This is because the distribution of arrival times to the meeting is asymmetrically distributed at or past the scheduled start time. No one<ref>Outside the German-speaking countries: Peculiar cultural factors (particularly ''[[späteankunftschande]]'' and ''[[früheankunftfreude]]'') are at work here which can skew the calculation, but do not displace the general thrust of the theory.</ref> arrives early, some people arrive late, and experienced meeting participants know of this asymmetric distribution and therefore time their own arrival to the expected functional starting time of the meeting, which in turn further retards that average start time.  


The functional starting time of a meeting is, thus not a constant but a variable, proportional to its intended population, but conditioned by the cultural disposition of its members. A meeting in Switzerland will start on time regardless of how many attendees are expected due to the overwhelming power of ''[[früheankunftfreude]]'', whose effects are barely felt in London.  
The functional starting time of a meeting is, thus not a constant but a variable, proportional to its intended population, but conditioned by the cultural disposition of its members. A meeting in Switzerland will start on time regardless of how many attendees are expected due to the overwhelming power of ''[[früheankunftfreude]]'',<ref>More or less, “the joy of punctuality”.</ref> whose effects are barely felt in London. One in Frankfurt will generally start early.
 
Consequently, there is thus a lower ''and'' an upper bound on the number of people possible in a viable meeting of a given duration. When combined with {{buchstein}}’s ''[[Convenimus ergo es|convenimus]]'' maxim, the First Law leads to the apparent [[paradox]] that, to be meaningful, a meeting must have more than one, but fewer than two, people.
 
There is a school of [[catholic]] thought that this is absolutely ''not'' a paradox, but is rather a profound truth about the commercial universe.


As with the Heisenberg uncertainty principle in physics, there are logical indeterminacies involved with congregating in a business environment. these have led to a recent extension of the [[JC]]’s first law, thus:
As with the Heisenberg uncertainty principle in physics, there are logical indeterminacies involved with congregating in a business environment. these have led to a recent extension of the [[JC]]’s first law, thus: