Template:20 days notice ISDA: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 10: Line 10:
And even that “by reference to” is heavily qualified:  {{{{{1}}}|Close-out Amount}}s<ref>In this essay, as elsewhere, I use “Close-out Amount” as a generic term to refer to the amount determined to be payable under a terminated Transaction, whether documented under a {{2002ma}} or a {{1992ma}}. I know there is no such thing as a “Close-out Amount” under a {{1992ma}}. Just go with me on this, ok?</ref>  are intended to be determined “as of” the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}, being the date designated in your Section {{{{{1}}}|6(a)}} notice which had to be within 20 days of that notice. Now that makes it seem like you are facing a rather untimely cliff-edge if you can’t practicably close out your whole hedge book in 20 days, but note:
And even that “by reference to” is heavily qualified:  {{{{{1}}}|Close-out Amount}}s<ref>In this essay, as elsewhere, I use “Close-out Amount” as a generic term to refer to the amount determined to be payable under a terminated Transaction, whether documented under a {{2002ma}} or a {{1992ma}}. I know there is no such thing as a “Close-out Amount” under a {{1992ma}}. Just go with me on this, ok?</ref>  are intended to be determined “as of” the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}, being the date designated in your Section {{{{{1}}}|6(a)}} notice which had to be within 20 days of that notice. Now that makes it seem like you are facing a rather untimely cliff-edge if you can’t practicably close out your whole hedge book in 20 days, but note:


{{quote|Each {{{{{1}}}|Close-out Amount}} will be determined as of the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} ''or, if that would not be [[commercially reasonable]], as of the date or dates following the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} as '''would''' be [[commercially reasonable]]''.<ref>This is in the definition of {{{{{1}}}|Close-out Amount}} ({{2002ma}}) and {{isda92prov|Loss}} ({{1992ma}}). Curiously, {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} in the {{1992ma}} does it slightly differently, saying “The party making the determination (or its agent) will request each {{isda92prov|Reference Market-maker}} to provide its quotation to the extent reasonably practicable as of the same day and time (without regard to different time zones) ''on or as soon as reasonably practicable after the relevant {{isda92prov|Early Termination Date}}''.” We ''guess'' that gives a bit of flexibility, but is not quite so clear-cut. We suppose the point is that the {{isda92prov|Non-Affected Party}} can presumably hit the prices offered by the {{isda92prov|Reference Market Maker}}s — making the enormous assumption any will actually provide a price — and so isn’t subject to any market risk; which is good. But on the other hand, block-trading a huge portfolio on an arbitrary day you had to set because of the random requirement for “not more than 20 days” is hardly calculated to help the Defaulting Party. You would like to think common-sense would prevail for those dinosaurs still on the {{1992ma}}, who are using the {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} concept. Then again, the fact that they are still on a {{1992ma}} twenty years after it was superseded suggests somewhat that common sense may be lacking somewhere in the relationship. </ref>}}
{{quote|Each {{{{{1}}}|Close-out Amount}} will be determined as of the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} ''or, if that would not be [[commercially reasonable]], as of the date or dates following the {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} as '''would''' be [[commercially reasonable]]''.<ref>This is in the definition of {{isdaprov|Close-out Amount}} ({{2002ma}}) and {{isda92prov|Loss}} ({{1992ma}}). Curiously, {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} in the {{1992ma}} does it slightly differently, saying “The party making the determination (or its agent) will request each {{isda92prov|Reference Market-maker}} to provide its quotation to the extent reasonably practicable as of the same day and time (without regard to different time zones) ''on or as soon as reasonably practicable after the relevant {{isda92prov|Early Termination Date}}''.” We ''guess'' that gives a bit of flexibility, but is not quite so clear-cut. We suppose the point is that the {{isda92prov|Non-Affected Party}} can presumably hit the prices offered by the {{isda92prov|Reference Market Maker}}s — making the enormous assumption any will actually provide a price — and so isn’t subject to any market risk; which is good. But on the other hand, block-trading a huge portfolio on an arbitrary day you had to set because of the random requirement for “not more than 20 days” is hardly calculated to help the Defaulting Party. You would like to think common-sense would prevail for those dinosaurs still on the {{1992ma}}, who are using the {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} concept. Then again, the fact that they are still on a {{1992ma}} twenty years after it was superseded suggests somewhat that common sense may be lacking somewhere in the relationship. </ref>}}


'''This is very important'''. This means<ref>Arguably unless you’re on a {{1992ma}} and using {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} — see the footnote above.</ref> you don’t have to liquidate a portfolio in its entirety within 20 days, or even take the values as of that {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}. If you can, you should — but it may well not be commercially reasonable — or even possible — to. The [[Lehman]] insolvency took ''months'' to unwind. Note also that [[commercial reasonableness]] is viewed from the Non-Affected Party’s perspective. It is not a licence to do whatever the hell you want — but the court won’t second guess prudent application of your own models.
'''This is very important'''. This means<ref>Arguably unless you’re on a {{1992ma}} and using {{isda92prov|Market Quotation}} — see the footnote above.</ref> you don’t have to liquidate a portfolio in its entirety within 20 days, or even take the values as of that {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}. If you can, you should — but it may well not be commercially reasonable — or even possible — to. The [[Lehman]] insolvency took ''months'' to unwind. Note also that [[commercial reasonableness]] is viewed from the Non-Affected Party’s perspective. It is not a licence to do whatever the hell you want — but the court won’t second guess prudent application of your own models.
Line 16: Line 16:
So this leaves the mystery of ''why'' a party designating an {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}, for any reason, wouldn’t just designate it ''now'' — and for those peculiar types who don’t want to do that, why there should be this arbitrary long-stop of 20 days.
So this leaves the mystery of ''why'' a party designating an {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}, for any reason, wouldn’t just designate it ''now'' — and for those peculiar types who don’t want to do that, why there should be this arbitrary long-stop of 20 days.


Remember the {{isdama}} was invented by banking folk: people who who view the Cosmos chiefly through the prism of [[indebtedness]]<ref>Hence, a {{{{{1}}}|Cross Default}} clause in the {{isdama}}. Well — can you think of another reason for it?</ref>. A [[lender]] whose [[borrower]] has defaulted will not dilly dally: she will bang in a default notice and seize whatever assets she can get her hand in ''poste haste''. I lend, you owe. I don’t muck about. [[Breakage costs]] on a [[loan]] are easy to calculate and they are not especially volatile. There is nothing to be gained by waiting around: interest continues to accrue, at a penalty rate: the longer I take to terminate my [[exposure]], the larger it is likely to be.
Remember the {{isdama}} was invented by banking folk: people who who view the Cosmos chiefly through the prism of [[indebtedness]]<ref>Hence, a Cross Default clause in the {{isdama}}. Well — can you think of another reason for it?</ref>. A [[lender]] whose [[borrower]] has defaulted will not dilly dally: she will bang in a default notice and seize whatever assets she can get her hand in ''poste haste''. I lend, you owe. I don’t muck about. [[Breakage costs]] on a [[loan]] are easy to calculate and they are not especially volatile. There is nothing to be gained by waiting around: interest continues to accrue, at a penalty rate: the longer I take to terminate my [[exposure]], the larger it is likely to be.


But, but, but. [[ISDA]]s are different. They are not, ''principally'', a contract of [[indebtedness]], and while a large uncollateralised [[mark-to-market]] [[exposure]]<ref>Such as the sort you could have if it were 1987 and the [[credit support annex]] ''hadn’t been invented''.</ref> is economically the ''same'' as indebtedness, the contract is [[bilateral]], these days almost always fully [[VM CSA|collateralised]], and who is indebted at any time is dependent on the net exposure: it can and does swing around.
But, but, but. [[ISDA]]s are different. They are not, ''principally'', a contract of [[indebtedness]], and while a large uncollateralised [[mark-to-market]] [[exposure]]<ref>Such as the sort you could have if it were 1987 and the [[credit support annex]] ''hadn’t been invented''.</ref> is economically the ''same'' as indebtedness, the contract is [[bilateral]], these days almost always fully [[VM CSA|collateralised]], and who is indebted at any time is dependent on the net exposure: it can and does swing around.
Line 22: Line 22:
Also, the [[mark-to-market]] exposure on [[swap]] {{{{{1}}}|transaction}} is a wildly volatile thing: With a [[loan]], less so: you know you have (a) [[principal]], (b) accrued [[interest]] and (c) [[break costs]] — the last of which might be significant for a long term [[fixed rate]] [[loan]],<ref>But are there such things in this day and age? Serious question.</ref> but generally will pale in comparison to the principal sum owed.
Also, the [[mark-to-market]] exposure on [[swap]] {{{{{1}}}|transaction}} is a wildly volatile thing: With a [[loan]], less so: you know you have (a) [[principal]], (b) accrued [[interest]] and (c) [[break costs]] — the last of which might be significant for a long term [[fixed rate]] [[loan]],<ref>But are there such things in this day and age? Serious question.</ref> but generally will pale in comparison to the principal sum owed.


So a swap counterparty who terminates might be [[out of the money]], and disinclined to terminate just now, hoping that a more benign market environment might be just around the corner to dig it out of its hole so that when it does pull its trigger, the {{{{{1}}}|Close-Out Amount}} will be favourable. This is still taking quite the market punt on a bust counterparty — by means of a [[European Option - Equity Derivatives Provision|European option]]<ref>A correspondent writes pointing out — quite correctly — that, once an {{{{{1}}}|Event of Default}} has happened, the option to send a {{{{{1}}}|6(a)}} Notice is [[American option|''American'']]. So it is — thanks to Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}}, a potentially open ended one — until you convert it into something ''like'' a [[European option]] by sending the notice and specifying a date in the future on which it takes place.</ref> — of course, and not the sort of thing a prudent risk manager would do,<ref>The silly [[FT book about derivatives|FT book]] is right about this, to be fair.</ref> but I don’t suppose banking folk can be expected to have understood this in 1986.
So a swap counterparty who terminates might be [[out of the money]], and disinclined to terminate just now, hoping that a more benign market environment might be just around the corner to dig it out of its hole so that when it does pull its trigger, the {{{{{1}}}|Close-Out Amount}} will be favourable. This is still taking quite the market punt on a bust counterparty — by means of a [[European Option - Equity Derivatives Provision|European option]]<ref>A correspondent writes pointing out — quite correctly — that, once an {{isdaprov|Event of Default}} has happened, the option to send a {{isdaprov|6(a)}} Notice is [[American option|''American'']]. So it is — thanks to Section {{isdaprov|2(a)(iii)}}, a potentially open ended one — until you convert it into something ''like'' a [[European option]] by sending the notice and specifying a date in the future on which it takes place.</ref> — of course, and not the sort of thing a prudent risk manager would do,<ref>The silly [[FT book about derivatives|FT book]] is right about this, to be fair.</ref> but I don’t suppose banking folk can be expected to have understood this in 1986.


Actually, even ''that'' makes little sense, since such a counterparty wouldn’t be obliged to close out at all, but could just suspend its obligations under Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} — something which it can (or could, at any rate, when the notice period was devised, in 1987) do indefinitely. To be sure, a {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} suspension is just that — a suspension; should one come eventually to terminate the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}}, those as-yet unperformed obligations will come back to haunt you as {{{{{1}}}|Unpaid Amount}}s, but at least here you retain control of the process and timing of close-out: it is an [[American option]], not a [[European option|European]] one. If you see the market moving against you, you can cash in your chips. So, ask yourself which is a bigger punt: that, the [[mark-to-market]] value you determine in 20 days — in a market that is likely to be a flaming wreck, by the way — better suits your book than the one you can actually trade on today, or on any day between now and that distant {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}?
Actually, even ''that'' makes little sense, since such a counterparty wouldn’t be obliged to close out at all, but could just suspend its obligations under Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} — something which it can (or could, at any rate, when the notice period was devised, in 1987) do indefinitely. To be sure, a {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} suspension is just that — a suspension; should one come eventually to terminate the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}}, those as-yet unperformed obligations will come back to haunt you as {{{{{1}}}|Unpaid Amount}}s, but at least here you retain control of the process and timing of close-out: it is an [[American option]], not a [[European option|European]] one. If you see the market moving against you, you can cash in your chips. So, ask yourself which is a bigger punt: that, the [[mark-to-market]] value you determine in 20 days — in a market that is likely to be a flaming wreck, by the way — better suits your book than the one you can actually trade on today, or on any day between now and that distant {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}}?


So we get back to an alternative, disappointing explanation: It is just [[flannel]].
So we get back to an alternative, disappointing explanation: It is just [[flannel]].