Template:Flawed asset capsule: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
No edit summary
 
(2 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 8: Line 8:
The “[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|bilaterality]]” of most derivatives arrangements means that either party may, net, be “[[out of the money]]” — that is, across all outstanding transactions, it would have to ''pay'' a net sum of money if all transactions were terminated. This is a notional debt that only becomes “due” as such if you designate an {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} under the Master Agreement. So an [[out-of-the-money]] {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} has a good reason therefore ''not'' to close out the ISDA. Why should it have to pay out just because a {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} has failed to perform its end of the bargain? On the other hand, if it forebears from terminating against a bankrupt counterparty the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} doesn’t want to have to continue stoically paying good money away to a bankrupt counterparty who isn’t reciprocating.  
The “[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|bilaterality]]” of most derivatives arrangements means that either party may, net, be “[[out of the money]]” — that is, across all outstanding transactions, it would have to ''pay'' a net sum of money if all transactions were terminated. This is a notional debt that only becomes “due” as such if you designate an {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} under the Master Agreement. So an [[out-of-the-money]] {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} has a good reason therefore ''not'' to close out the ISDA. Why should it have to pay out just because a {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} has failed to perform its end of the bargain? On the other hand, if it forebears from terminating against a bankrupt counterparty the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} doesn’t want to have to continue stoically paying good money away to a bankrupt counterparty who isn’t reciprocating.  


An [[out-of-the-money]] {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} seems, therefore, to be in a bit of a cleft stick.
An [[out-of-the-money]], {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} seems to be, therefore, in a bit of a cleft stick.


Section 2(a)(iii) allows the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} the best of both worlds. The [[conditions precedent]] to payment not being satisfied it can just stop performing, and sit on its hands, and thereby not thereby crystallising the [[mark-to-market]] loss implied by its [[out-of-the-money]] position. The {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}}’s “asset” its right to be paid, or delivered to under the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} is “flawed” in the sense that its rights don’t apply for so long as ''the [[conditions precedent]] to payment are not fulfilled''.  
Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} allows the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} the best of both worlds. The [[conditions precedent]] to payment not being satisfied, it can just stop performing, and sit on its hands and thereby not thereby crystallise the [[mark-to-market]] loss implied by its [[out-of-the-money]] position.  
 
The {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}}’s “asset” its right to be paid, or delivered to under the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} is “flawed” in the sense that its rights don’t apply for so long as ''the [[conditions precedent]] to payment are not fulfilled''.  


Conceivably you ''could'' invoke a flawed asset provision even if you were [[in-the-money]], but you would be mad to.
Conceivably you ''could'' invoke a flawed asset provision even if you were [[in-the-money]], but you would be mad to.
=====Which events?=====
====Which events?====
Exactly ''which'' default events can trigger a flawed asset clause will depend on the contract. Under the {{isdama}} it {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} and even {{{{{1}}}|Potential Events of Default}} do, but {{{{{1}}}|Termination Event}}s and {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}}s do not. {{{{{1}}}|Termination Event}}s are softer, “hey look, it’s no-one’s fault, it’s just one of those things” kind of close outs, so that makes some sense — but on the other hand this is not really true of {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}}s, which tend to be credit-driven and with more “culpability” and “event-of-defaulty-ness” about them. This is, a bit dissonant, but there are far greater dissonances, so we park this one and carry on.
Exactly ''which'' default events can trigger a flawed asset clause will depend on the contract. Under the ISDA, {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} and even ''Potential'' {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} do, but {{{{{1}}}|Termination Event}}s and {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}}s do not.
 
This is because most Termination Events are softer, “hey look, it’s no-one’s fault, it’s just one of those things” kind of closeouts — but this is not really true of {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}}s, which tend to be credit-driven and girded with more “culpability” and “event-of-defaulty-ness”.  
 
This is, a bit dissonant, but there are far greater dissonances, so we park this one and carry on.
 
====2(a)(iii) in a time of Credit Support====
Flawed assets entered the argot in a simpler, more (''less''?) peaceable time when two-way, zero-threshold, daily-margined collateral arrangements were an unusual sight. Nor, in those times, were dealers often of the view that they might be on the wrong end of a flawed assets clause. They presumed if anyone was going bust, it would be their client. Because — the house always wins, right? The events of [[Global financial crisis|September 2018]] were, therefore, quite the chastening experience.


=====2(a)(iii) in a time of Credit Support=====
In any case without collateral, a {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} could, be nursing a large, unfunded [[mark-to-market]] liability which it would not want to pay out just because the clot at the other end of the contract had driven his fund into a ditch.  
Flawed assets entered the argot in a simpler, more (''less''?) peaceable time when two-way, zero-threshold, daily-margined collateral arrangements were a fantastical sight. It was therefore reasonably likely that a {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} might be nursing a large unfunded [[mark-to-market]] liability which it would not want to have to pay out on just because the clot at the other end of the contract had driven his fund into a ditch. A large uncollateralised position is a less likely scenario in these days of mandatory [[regulatory margin]] in which counterparties generally cash-collateralise their net market positions to, or near, zero each day.  


Nor, we think, did it occur to dealers, who typically insisted on the flawed assets clause, that they might be on the wrong end of it. The events of [[Global financial crisis|September 2018]] were, therefore, quite the chastening experience.
That was then: in these days of mandatory [[regulatory margin]], counterparties generally cash-collateralise their net market positions to, or near, zero each day, so a large uncollateralised position is a much less likely scenario. So most people will be happy enough just closing out: the optionality not to is not very valuable.