Template:Isda 2(a)(iii) summ: Difference between revisions

uote
No edit summary
(uote)
Line 1: Line 1:
====Flawed Assets====
{{quote|
{{d|Flawed asset|/flɔːd ˈæsɛt/|n}}
A financial asset that looks good, but thanks to a carefully buried [[conditions precedent]], is not there when you, and more importantly, your insolvency administrator, wants it.}}


{{drop|I|n the language}} of financial obligations, one’s rights to future payments under a contract are an asset. You own them and, all other things being equal, can ''deal'' with themcthat is, sell or raise money against them — the same way you can sell or mortgage a house, car, a portfolio of equities, or some [[Bitcoin|decentralised cryptographic tokens representing abstract capital]].
=== Assets, and flawed assets ===
What is the big deal about this, then? Well, it turns your ISDA into a “flawed asset”.
{{quote|{{d|Flawed asset|/flɔːd ˈæsɛt/|n|}}


“Assets” have a few “[[ontological]]” properties, one of which is ''continuity'', in time and space. They might rust, depreciate, go out of fashion or stop working properly but they are nevertheless, existentially, still ''there'', at least until you do sell them. They therefore have some value to you, however parlous the state of your affairs might otherwise be.  
A financial asset that looks good, but thanks to a carefully buried [[conditions precedent]], is not there when you, and more importantly, your insolvency administrator, most wants it.}}


This makes accounting for assets possible, albeit difficult.  
{{drop|I|n the language}} of financial obligations, the right to future payments under a contract is an ''asset''. The creditor owns that right and, all other things being equal, can ''deal'' with it — that is, sell or raise money against it — the same way it can sell or mortgage a house, car, a portfolio of equities, or some [[Bitcoin|decentralised cryptographic tokens representing abstract capital]].


==== Flawed Assets ====
Assets have certain “[[ontological]]” properties, such as ''continuity'' ''in time and space.'' They might rust, depreciate, go out of fashion or stop working properly but they are nevertheless, existentially, still ''there''. While you own them they therefore have some value to you, however parlous the state of your affairs might otherwise be.
<blockquote><big>[[Flawed asset]]</big>


/flɔːd ˈæsɛt/ (''n''.)
Should your stars line up so that some official comes to be drawing up a closing account of your earthly financial existence — should you become [[Insolvency|''bankrupt'']], heaven forfend — your assets can reliably be popped onto the “plus” side of the ledger. The difficulty subsists in working out what they are worth, but at least they are there.


A financial asset that looks good, but thanks to a carefully buried [[conditions precedent]], is not there when you, and more importantly, your insolvency administrator, wants it.</blockquote>In the language of financial obligations, one’s rights to future payments under a contract are an asset. You own them and, all other things being equal, can therefore ''deal'' with them — that is, sell or raise money against them — the same way you can sell or mortgage a house, car, a portfolio of equities, or some [[Bitcoin|decentralised cryptographic tokens representing abstract capital]]. ''[Really? — Ed.]''
This continuity is important to the administration of failing enterprises wherever they are based. It is a rude shock to find the assets you thought were there have without good explanation, gone. Many countries have rules preventing company managers from selling or giving away assets at an undervalue or otherwise granting unfair preferences as impending disaster looms. And nor can they enter contracts, even in times of fair weather, which would have the effect of granting unfair preferences, or depriving other creditors, should the clouds roll in.


“Assets” have a few “[[ontological]]” properties, one of which is ''continuity'', in time and space. Assets might rust, depreciate, go out of fashion or stop working properly but they are nevertheless, existentially, still ''there'', at least until you do sell them. They therefore have some value to you, however parlous the state of your affairs might otherwise be.
An asset that doesn’t have that quality of continuity: that suddenly isn’t there, or that has the unnerving quality of winking in and out of sight at inopportune moments — is thus somehow imperfect: “flawed”.  


This makes accounting for assets possible, albeit difficult. Should your fates line up so that some official comes to be drawing up a closing account of your earthly financial existence should you become ''[[Insolvency|bankrupt]]'', heaven forfend — your assets can reliability be popped onto the “plus” side of the ledger. The difficulty subsists in working out what they are worth, but at least they are there.
Section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]] seems to have that effect on a [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]]’s claims under an ISDA  its asset. Just when the [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]] goes insolvent or fails to perform, the [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]] is entitled to suspend the performance of its obligations without terminating the [[Transaction - ISDA Provision|Transaction]]. Not entitled, even — as we will see, it just happens.


This continuity is important to the administration of failing enterprises wherever they are based, and so many countries have rules preventing company managers hurriedly disposing of their assets as impending disaster looms. Managers can’t therefore grant unfair preferences, by selling or giving away  assets at an undervalue. And they can’t enter contracts, even in times of fair weather, which might have the effect of giving some creditors and counterparties unfair preferences over others, should the clouds roll in.
Should the [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]] then cure the default, the [[Transaction - ISDA Provision|Transaction]] resumes and the [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]] must resume all its obligations, including the suspended ones. But for so long as the default is not cured, the [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]] does not have to do anything. The [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]] is left hanging there, with this “flawed asset”.


Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} has exactly that effect on a {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}}’s claims under an ISDA. Just when it goes insolvent or fails materially to perform, its “asset” represented by the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}}, perhaps temporarily, vanishes. It allows a {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} to indefinitely suspend its performance of its obligations under a {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} without terminating the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}}. Should the {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} cure the default, the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} resumes and the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} must resume all its obligations, including the suspended ones. But for so long as the default is not cured, the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} does not have to do anything but keeps the option to terminate (thereby crystallising the loss at any time.
=== Insolvency regimes: not keen. ===
{{drop|T|he United States}} [[Bankruptcy Code]] renders unenforceable terms terminating or modifying a contract that are triggered by the simple fact of insolvency proceedings. These are known as “[[ipso facto]]” clauses, because the simple ''fact'' of bankruptcy “in itself” triggers the clause.


So an asset that doesn’t have that quality of continuity: that suddenly isn’t there, or that has the unnerving quality of winking in and out of existence at inopportune moments — especially at times of its owner’s existence fitfulness — is somehow imperfect: “flawed”. 
If Section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]] were an ipso facto clause, it would not be enforceable. Whether it ''is'' an [[ipso facto clause]] is a subject of vigorous but tiresome debate. For our purposes, that people don’t easily agree about it is all you need to know.


====Insolvency regimes: not fans.====
The UK has no statutory equivalent of America’s [[ipso facto rule]], but hundreds of years ago resourceful common law judges “discovered” an “anti‑deprivation” rule to the effect that, in the honeyed words of Sir William Page Wood V.C., in ''Whitmore v Mason'' (1861) 2J&H 204:{{quote|
{{drop|I|n the United}} States, there is a provision in the [[Bankruptcy Code]] rendering unenforceable any contract terms providing for termination or modification that are triggered by the simple fact of insolvency proceedings. These are known as “[[ipso facto]]” clauses, because the simple ''fact'' of bankruptcy “in itself” triggers the clause. If Section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]] were an ipso facto clause, it would not be enforceable.
“no person possessed of property can reserve that property to himself until he shall become bankrupt, and then provide that, in the event of his becoming bankrupt, it shall pass to another and not his creditors”.}}
This required some wilfulness on the bankrupt’s part and not just inadvertence or lucky hap, but still: if you set out to defeat the standing bankruptcy laws do not expect easily to get away with it.
 
It seems, at any rate, that Section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]], ''might'' resemble some kind of intended deprivation; merely crystallising one’s existing position and stopping it from going further down the Swanee, as one might do by closing out altogether, seems less likely to.
 
Anyway: be aware: Section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]] attracts insolvency lawyers.
 
=== Rationale: avoiding a cleft stick ===
{{drop|W|e can have}} a fine time rabbiting away about the ontology of assets, but isn’t there a more basic question: why would a [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]], presented with a counterparty in default, ever ''not'' want to just close out?


Whether Section 2(a)(iii) ''is'' an [[ipso facto clause]] is a subject of vigorous but tiresome debate. For our purposes, the fact that people don’t easily agree about it is all you need to know: this makes a silly contractual provision even more cavalier.
It all comes down to [[Moneyness|''moneyness'']].


While the UK has no statutory equivalent of America’s [[ipso facto rule]], hundreds of years ago resourceful common law judges “discovered” an “anti‑deprivation” rule that, in the honeyed words of Sir William Page Wood V.C., in ''Whitmore v Mason'' (1861) 2J&H 204:
The “[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|bilaterality]]” of a swap transaction means that either party may, net, be “[[out of the money]]” — that is, it would have to ''pay'' a net sum of money were the Transaction terminated — at any time. Unless something dramatic happens, this “moneyness” is only a “notional” debt: it only becomes “due” if an [[Early Termination Date - ISDA Provision|Early Termination Date]] is designated under the Master Agreement.
{{quote|
 
“no person possessed of property can reserve that property to himself until he shall become bankrupt, and then provide that, in the event of his becoming bankrupt, it shall pass to another and not his creditors”.}}
So an [[out-of-the-money]], [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]] has a good reason ''not'' to close out the ISDA. Doing so would oblige it to crystallise and pay out a mark-to-market loss. Why should it have to do that just because a [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]] has failed to perform its end of the bargain?
 
On the other hand, the Defaulting Party is, er, ''ipso facto'', not holding up its end of the bargain. Just as our innocent Non-defaulting Party does not wish to realise a loss by terminating, nor does it want to have to stoically pay good money away to a Defaulting Party who isn’t paying anything back.
 
A cleft stick, therefore.
 
Section 2(a)(iii) allows our [[Non-defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Non-defaulting Party]] the best of both worlds. The [[conditions precedent]] to payment not being satisfied, it can just stop performing and sit on its hands — thereby neither crystallising its ugly [[mark-to-market]] position nor pouring perfectly good money away (which is a form of drip-feeding away that mark-to-market position, if you think about it).


This required some wilfulness on the bankrupt’s part and not just inadvertence or lucky hap, but still: if you set out to defeat the standing bankruptcy laws do not expect easily to get away with it.  
So much so good for the Non-defaulting Party.  


It seems, at any rate, that Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}}, might resemble some kind of intended deprivation; merely crystallising one’s existing position and stopping it from going further down the Swanee, as one might do by closing out altogether, seems less so.  
But the [[Defaulting Party - ISDA Provision|Defaulting Party]]’s “asset” — its contingent claim for its in-the-money position against the Non-defaulting Party — is compromised. This, for an insolvency administrator and all the Defaulting Party’s other creditors, is a bummer. It deprives them of the “asset” represented by the Transaction.


Anyway: be aware: Talk of Section 2(a)(iii) attracts insolvency lawyers. That ought to be reason enough to keep schtum about it.
===Which events?===
{{drop|E|xactly ''which'' default}} events can trigger the suspension? Under the [[ISDA Master Agreement|ISDA]], [[Events of Default - ISDA Provision|Events of Default]] and even ''Potential'' Events of Default do, but [[Termination Event - ISDA Provision|Termination Events]] and [[Additional Termination Event - ISDA Provision|Additional Termination Events]] do not. This is because ''most'' [[Termination Event - ISDA Provision|Termination Events]] are softer, “Hey look, it’s no one’s fault, it’s just one of those things” kind of events. This is not usually true of [[Additional Termination Event - ISDA Provision|''Additional'' Termination Events]], though: they tend to be credit-driven, and girded with more “culpability” and “event-of-defaulty-ness”. So this is a bit dissonant, but there are far greater dissonances, so we park this one and carry on.


====On avoiding a cleft stick====
[[JC]] has seen valiant efforts to insert [[Additional Termination Events - ISDA Provision|Additional Termination Events]] to section [[2(a)(iii) - ISDA Provision|2(a)(iii)]], and ''Potential'' [[Additional Termination Event - ISDA Provision|Additional Termination Events]], a class of things that does not exist outside the laboratory, and must therefore be defined. All this for the joy of invoking a clause that is highly unlikely to ever come into play, and which makes little sense in the first place.
{{drop|W|w can have}} a fine time rabbiting away about the ontology of assets for sure, but isn’t there a more basic question: why would a Non-defaulting Party, presented with a counterparty in default, ever ''not'' want to just close out?


It all comes down to ''[[moneyness]]''. The “[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|bilaterality]]” of a swap {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} means that either party may, net, be “[[out of the money]]that is, it would have to ''pay'' a net sum of money if the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} were terminated — at any time. Unless something dramatic happens, this “moneyness” is only a “notional” debt: it only becomes “due” if an {{{{{1}}}|Early Termination Date}} is designated under the Master Agreement.
===Why the ISDA?====
<blockquote>[[Herculio|''HERCULIO'']]: All well-meant, good [[Triago]]. Be not sour


So an [[out-of-the-money]], {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} has a good reason ''not'' to close out the ISDA. Doing so would oblige it to crystallise and pay out a mark-to-market loss. Why should it have to do that just because a  {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} has failed to perform its end of the bargain?
These are not grapes.


On the other hand, the {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} is, er, ''ipso facto'', not holding up its end of the bargain. Just as our innocent {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} does not wish to realise a loss by terminating, nor does it want to have to stoically pay good money away to a {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}} who isn’t paying anything back.
[[Triago|''TRIAGO'']]: Indeed not sir: rather, scrapes.


A cleft stick.
And scars and knocks — the job-lot doggedly sustained.


Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} allows our {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} the best of both worlds. The [[conditions precedent]] to payment not being satisfied, it can just stop performing and sit on its hands — thereby neither crystallising its ugly [[mark-to-market]] position nor pouring perfectly good money away (which is a form of drip-feeding away that mark-to-market position, if you think about it).
[[Herculio|''HERCULIO'']]: (''Aside'') Some more than others. The odd one feigned.


So much so good for the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}}. 
But come, Sir Tig: what unrests you here?


But the {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}}’s “asset” — its contingent claim for its in-the-money position against the {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} — is compromised. This, for an insolvency administrator and all the {{{{{1}}}|Defaulting Party}}’s other creditors, is a bummer. It deprives them of the “asset” represented by the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}}.
[[Triago|''TRIAGO'']] (''waving paper''): A tract from a brother clerk in America.
====Which events?====
Exactly which default events can trigger the suspension? Under the ISDA, {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} and even ''Potential'' {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} do, but {{{{{1}}}|Termination Events}} and {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Events}} do not. This is because most {{{{{1}}}|Termination Events}} are softer, “Hey look, it’s no one’s fault, it’s just one of those things” kind of events. This is not usually true of ''Additional'' Termination Events, though: they tend to be credit-driven, and girded with more “culpability” and “event-of-defaulty-ness”. So this is a bit dissonant, but there are far greater dissonances, so we park this one and carry on.


We have seen valiant efforts to insert Additional Termination Events to section 2(a)(iii), and “Potential Additional Termination Events”, a class of things that does not exist outside the laboratory, so must therefore be defined. All this for the joy of invoking a clause that makes little sense in the first place.
[[Herculio|''HERCULIO'']]: Cripes abroad. Grim tidings?
====2(a)(iii) in a time of Credit Support====
Flawed assets entered the argot in a simpler, more (''less''?) peaceable time when two-way, zero-threshold, daily-margined collateral arrangements were an unusual sight. Nor, in those times, were dealers often of the view that they might be on the wrong end of a flawed assets clause. They presumed if anyone was going bust, it would be their client. Because — the house always wins, right? The events of [[Global financial crisis|September 2018]] were, therefore, quite the chastening experience.


In any case without collateral, a {{{{{1}}}|Non-defaulting Party}} could, be nursing a large, unfunded [[mark-to-market]] liability which it would not want to pay out just because the clot at the other end of the contract had driven his fund into a ditch.  
[[Triago|''TRIAGO'']]: Forsooth: it wears the colours of a fight.


That was then: in these days of mandatory [[regulatory margin]], counterparties generally cash-collateralise their net market positions to, or near, zero each day, so a large uncollateralised position is a much less likely scenario. So most people will be happy enough just closing out: the optionality not to is not very valuable.
A word-scape stain’d with tightly kernèd face
====The problem with bilateral agreements====
{{Quote|
{{Script|Triago}}: Forsooth: it wears the colours of a fight. <Br>
A word-scape stain’d with tightly kernèd face<Br>
And girded round with fontish weaponry.<Br>
{{Script|Herculio}} (''inspecting the document''): Verily, convenantry this dark<Br>
Speaks of litiginous untrust.<Br>
:—{{Otto}}, {{dsh}}
}}
As we have remarked before, most financing contracts are decidedly one-sided. One party — the dealer, broker, bank: we lump these various financial service providers together as ''The Man'' — provides services, lends money and manufactures risk outcomes; the other — the customer — ''consumes'' them.


Generally, the customer presents risks to The Man, and not vice versa. In a loan, all the “fontish weaponry” is pointed in the same direction: the customer’s. It goes without saying that should the customer “run out of road”, The Man stands to ''lose'' something. What is to be done should ''The Man'' run out of road is left undetermined but implicitly it is unlikely, and not expected to change anything for the customer. Whatever you owe, you will continue to owe; just to someone else.
And girded round with fontish weaponry.


Though the ISDA is also, in practice, a “risk creation contract” and has these same characteristics, it is not, in ''theory'', designed like one. ''Either'' party can be [[out-of-the-money]], and either party can blow up. The ISDA’s fontish weaponry points ''both ways''.
[[Herculio|''HERCULIO'']] (''inspecting the document''): Verily, convenantry this dark


This presented dealers with an unusual scenario: what happens if ''you'' blow up when ''I'' owe you money? I might not want to crystallise my contract: that will involve me paying you a [[mark-to-market]] replacement cost I hadn’t budgeted for paying out just now. (This is less true in these days of mandatory [[variation margin]] — that is one of JC’s main objections — but the {{isdama}} was forged well before this modern era).
Speaks of litiginous untrust.


The ISDA answers this with the “[[flawed asset]]” provision of Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}}. This allows an innocent, but [[out-of-the-money]], party faced with its counterparty’s default, to not close out the ISDA, but just freeze its own obligations until the default situation is resolved.
[[Otto Büchstein]], [[Die Schweizer Heulsuse|''Die Schweizer Heulsuse'']]</blockquote>Why, then, is this flawed assets business special to ISDA? ''Is'' it special to ISDA?


There is an argument the flawed asset clause wasn’t a good idea even then, but a better one that it is a bad idea now, but like so many parts of this sacred, blessed form it is there and, for hundreds and thousands of ISDA trading arrangements, we are stuck with it.
Normal financing contracts are, by nature, one-sided. Loans, for example. One party — the dealer, broker, bank: we lump these various financial service providers together as ''The Man'' — provides services, lends money and “manufactures” risk outcomes; the other — the customer — ''consumes'' them.


Ask a chary credit officer what she thinks of Section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} and her eyes are sure to glister as she regales you with the countless times it's got her out of a scrape at the first sign of {{{{{1}}}|Potential Event of Default}}. Regulators are less enamoured, especially after the [[ global financial crisis]], and took some steps to impose at least as “use it or lose it” drop-dead point, but institutional inertia and the brick wall of reality has long since arrested that drift.
So, generally, the customer presents risks to The Man, and not vice versa. If the customer fails, it can’t repay its loan. All the “fontish weaponry” is therefore pointed at the customer.


====Does not apply to {{{{{1}}}|Termination Events}}====
Though the ISDA is also a “risk creation contract” with these same characteristics, it is not designed like one. ''Either'' party can be out of the money, and either party can blow up. The fontish weaponry points ''both ways''.
Since most {{isdama}}s that reach the life support machine in an ICU get there by dint of a {{{{{1}}}|Failure to Pay}} or {{{{{1}}}|Bankruptcy}} this does not, in point of fact, amount to much, but it is worth noting that while {{{{{1}}}|Event of Default}}s — and even events that are not yet but with the passing of time might ''become'' {{{{{1}}}|Events of Default}} — can, without formal action by the {{{{{1}}}|non-Defaulting Party}} trigger a {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} suspension, a mere Section {{{{{1}}}|5(b)}} {{{{{1}}}|Termination Event}} — even a catastrophic one like an {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}} (such as a [[NAV trigger]], [[Key person clause|key person event]] or some such) — cannot, until the {{{{{1}}}|Transaction}} has been formally terminated, at which point it really ought to go without saying.  


This might rile and unnerve [[credit officer]]s by nature an easily perturbed lot — but given our arguments below for what a train wreck the whole {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}} thing is, those of stabler personalities will consider this in the round a good thing.
This presented dealers with an unusual scenario: what happens if ''you'' blow up when ''I'' owe you money? That could not happen in a loan.  It is less likely to happen under a swap these days, too, thanks to the arrival of mandatory [[variation margin]] — that is one of JC’s main objections — but the [[ISDA Master Agreement]] was forged well before this modern era.


Nevertheless, the [[JC]] has seen valiant efforts to insert {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Events}} to section {{{{{1}}}|2(a)(iii)}}, and — ''quel horreur'' — ''Potential'' {{{{{1}}}|Additional Termination Event}}s, a class of things that does not exist outside the laboratory, and must therefore be defined. All this for the joy of invoking a clause that doesn’t make any sense in the first place.
There is an argument the flawed asset clause wasn’t a good idea even then, but a better one that it is a bad idea now, but like so many parts of this sacred, blessed form it is there and, for hundreds and thousands of ISDA trading arrangements, we are stuck with it.


“Some things are better left unsaid,” said no [[ISDA ninja]] ever.
===Developments between editions===
===Developments between editions===
====“...a condition precedent for the purpose of this Section 2(a)(iii) ...”====
====“...a condition precedent for the purpose of this Section 2(a)(iii) ...”====