Template:M intro isda Party A and Party B: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
No edit summary
 
(16 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{quote|{{D|Bilateral|/ˌbaɪˈlætᵊrᵊl/|adj}}Having, or relating to, two sides; affecting both sides equally.}}
{{quote|{{D|Bilateral|/ˌbaɪˈlætᵊrᵊl/|adj}}Having, or relating to, two sides; affecting both sides equally.}}


{{smallcaps|[[Party A and Party B - ISDA Provision|In this episode]]}} the JC considers the “bilateral” nature of the {{isdama}}, why swap participants alone amongst financial players are called “[[counterparty|counterparties]]”, and what this confusing “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}” business is all about.  
{{drop|[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|I]]|n this episode}} [[JC]] considers the “bilateral” nature of the {{isdama}}, why swap participants alone amongst financial players are called “[[counterparty|counterparties]]”, and what this confusing “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}” business is all about.  


The unpresumptuous way it labels the parties to a Transaction sets the ISDA apart from its fellow [[finance contract]]s. They give it a sort of otherworldly aloofness; a sense of utopian equality; social justice almost. Other [[finance contract]]s label their participants to make it clear who, in the [[power structure]], is who: a [[loan]] has a “[[Lender]]” — the [[bank]]; always the master — and a “[[Borrower]]” — the punter; always the servant. A brokerage agreement has a “[[Broker]]” (master) and “[[Customer]]” (servant). Okay, I know ''theoretically'' the master/servant dynamic is meant to be the other way around — the customer is king and everything — but come on: when it comes to finance it isn’t, is it? We are ''users'', all hooked up to the great battery grid, for the pleasure of our banking overlords and the [[The domestication of law|pan-dimensional mice]] who control them.
The unpresumptuous way it labels the parties to a Transaction sets the ISDA apart from its fellow [[finance contract]]s. They give it a sort of otherworldly aloofness; a sense of utopian equality. Other [[finance contract]]s label their participants to make it clear who, in the [[power structure]], is who: a [[loan]] has a “[[Lender]]” — the [[bank]]; always the master — and a “[[Borrower]]” — the punter; always the servant. A brokerage agreement has a “[[Broker]]” (master) and a “[[Customer]]” (servant).  
 
Okay, I know ''theoretically'' the master/servant dynamic is meant to be the other way around — the customer is king and everything — but come on: when it comes to finance it isn’t, is it? We are ''users'', all hooked up to the great battery grid, for the pleasure of our banking overlords and the [[The domestication of law|pan-dimensional mice]] who control them.


But not when it comes to the {{isdama}}. From the outset, the [[First Men]] who framed it opted for the more gnomic, interchangeable and ''equal'' labels “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.
But not when it comes to the {{isdama}}. From the outset, the [[First Men]] who framed it opted for the more gnomic, interchangeable and ''equal'' labels “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.


Why? Well, we learn it from our supervising associate, when we first encounter a [[Schedule - ISDA Provision|Schedule]]. ''[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|Bilaterality]]''.
Why? Well, we learn it from our supervising associate, when we first encounter a [[Schedule - ISDA Provision|Schedule]].  
 
''[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|Bilaterality]]''.


===Bilaterality===
===Bilaterality===
{{smallcaps|A belief in}} even-handedness gripped the ones whose [[deep magic]] forged the runes of that ancient [[First Swap]]. Not just a two-sided structure — most private contractual arrangements have that — but a ''symmetrical'' one, lacking the relationship of dominance and subservience that traditional finance contracts imply. Unusually here there is not necessarily a large, institutional “have” indulging a small commercial “have-not” with its favours in the form of loaned money or extended credit, for which privilege the lender can extract excruciating [[covenant]]s, giving not a jot in return, and enjoy a preferred place amongst the [[customer]]’s many scrapping creditors.
{{drop|A|belief in}} even-handedness gripped the ones whose [[deep magic]] forged the runes of that ancient [[First Swap]]. It has not just a two-sided structure — most private contractual arrangements have that — but a ''symmetrical'' one, lacking the dominance and subservience that traditional finance contracts imply.  


But [[swaps]], as the [[First Men]] saw them, are not like that. Not ''necessarily''.
In the ISDA there is not — ''necessarily'' — a large “have” indulging a small “have-not” with favours of loaned money, for which it extracts excruciating [[covenant]]s, gives not a jot in return, and enjoys a preferred place amongst the [[customer]]’s many scrapping creditors.


“A swap,” they decreed, “shall be an exchange among peers. It is an equal-opportunity sort of thing; righteous in that, under its auspices, one is neither lender nor borrower, but simply an honest rival for the favour of the Lady Fortune, however capricious may she be.
[[Swaps]], as the [[First Men]] saw them, would not be like that. Not ''necessarily''.


“Thus, those who swap things are not master and servant, but equals. ''Rivals''. Let us call them ‘Counterparties’.”
“A swap shall be an exchange among peers: an equal-opportunity, righteous sort of thing under whose auspices, one is neither lender nor borrower, but simply an honest rival for the favour of Lady Fortune, however capricious may she be. Those who ''swap'' things are not master and servant, but ''rivals''.  


And, to be sure, swaps ''are'' different from loans and brokerage arrangements. They start off “at market”, where all is square. Either party may be long or short, fixed or floating: at the moment the trade is struck, the world infused with glorious possibility.  
“Let us call them ''Counterparties''.


One fellow’s fortunes may rise or fall relative to the other’s and, as a result, she may ''owe'' (in the vernacular, be “[[out-of-the-money]]”) or ''be owed'' (“[[in-the-money]]”).  
This foundation myth imagines “swaps” in a pure, innocent, trading-bubble-gum-cards-in-the-playground way.  


Covenants, privileges of collateral, credit support and so on may, thereby, flow either way. They may flow ''both'' ways. In our time of [[regulatory margin]], they usually do.
“I have two Emerson Fittipaldis, you have two Mario Andrettis, we can increase each other’s net happiness and thereby the world’s by swapping so we both have one of each.


And swaps, too, are the preserve of professional investors, who know what they are doing. Usually, they know it better than the bank employees they face, having once themselves ''been'' bank employees. Moms and pops, [[Belgian dentist]]s and the like may take loans, buy bonds, have a flutter on the share market and even trade cryptocurrencies but they don’t, and never have, entered {{isdama}}s.<ref>They may trade [[contracts for difference]] and make spread bets with brokers, but these are standardised, smaller contracts.</ref> The ISDA is for grown-ups. Equals.
In the playground there are no brokers or dealers of bubble gum cards to intermediate, make markets and provide liquidity, let alone a trusted central clearer. It is a peer-to-peer, decentralised marketplace.<ref>Oh, wait. Hang on. There ''was''. It was Peason Minor in 3B. That made a two-way market in foopballers, F1 drivers and Top Trumps military planes and supercars. That guy was incredible. Wonder what he’s doing now. [''CIO at GSAM — Ed.''] Okay so most metaphors don’t bear close examination.</ref>


That said, other than below the dotted lines where you type the counterparty names, the pre-printed part of {{isdama}} itself does not use the expressions “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” or “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”. [[2002 ISDA wikitext|Have a look, if you don’t believe me]]. Being genuinely bilateral, it never has to.  
And, to be sure, swaps ''are'' different from [[loan]]s and brokerage arrangements. They start “at market”, where all is square. Either party may be long or short, fixed or floating: at the moment the trade is struck, the world infused with glorious possibility.  


Party-specific labels are only needed once the studied symmetry of the Master Agreement gives way to the need, articulated in in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} and {{isdaprov|Confirmation}}s, to stipulate who is taking which side on a given trade, giving which covenant or submitting to which {{isdaprov|Additional Termination Event}}. They may be equals, but we still need to know who is going to pay the [[fixed rate]] and who the [[Floating rate|floating]]; which thresholds, maxima, minima, covenants, details, agents and terms apply to which party. This much is necessarily different. Nothing beyond: the {{isdama}} assumes you already know who is who, having agreed it in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}}.
One fellow’s fortunes may rise or fall relative to the other’s and, as a result, she may ''owe'' (in the vernacular, be [[out-of-the-money]]”) or ''be owed'' (“[[in-the-money]]”) at different times as the transaction wends its way to maturity.  


So we agree: for this swap trading relationship we will call you “Party B”, and me “Party A”. Beyond these colourless and forgettable labels, we are equal. They are maddeningly forgettable: harking from a time where the idea of “find and replace all” in an electronic document seemed like [[Tipp-Ex]]-denying, devilish magic — it might have been easier — and saved some curial angst— had parties been able to use unique identifying labels across their agreement portfolios.  
Covenants, collateral, credit support and so on may, thereby, flow either way. They may flow ''both'' ways. In our time of [[regulatory margin]], they usually do.


{{Quote|It was, I am afraid, a rather sloppily drafted document. First, it described LBIE as Party A and LBF as Party B, contrary to the Schedule which gave them the opposite descriptions.
And swaps, too, are the preserve of professional investors, who know what they are doing. Usually, they know it better than the bank employees they face, having once themselves ''been'' bank employees. Mums and dads, [[Belgian dentist]]s and the like may take loans, buy bonds, have a flutter on the share market and even trade cryptocurrencies but they don’t, and never have, entered {{isdama}}s.<ref>They may trade [[contracts for difference]] and make spread bets with brokers, but these are standardised, smaller contracts.</ref> The ISDA is for grown-ups. Equals.
:—Briggs, J, in ''Lehman Brothers International (Europe) v. Lehman Brothers Finance S.A.'' [2012] EWHC 1072 (Ch)}}


Being ''so'' generic, the “Party A” and “Party B” labels can lead to practical difficulties: a [[dealer]] with thirty thousand counterparties wants to be “Party A” every time, just for peace of mind and literary continuity when perusing its collection of Schedules, as we know [[dealer]]s on occasion are minded to do.<ref>They are not.</ref> This is not just a matter of having to play in your change strip every now and then: if, here and there, a dealer must be “Party B” having lost the toss to a counterparty who also insists on being Party A, this can lead to anxious moments, should one have momentarily forgotten the switch during the negotiation and assigned your carefully-argued infinite [[IM]] {{csaprov|Threshold}} to the other guy.
So much so that, other than below the dotted lines where you type the counterparty names, the pre-printed part of {{isdama}} itself does not even use the expressions “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” or “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”. Being genuinely bilateral, it never has to.  


Frights like this are, in their way, quite energising, if you pick them up during the “four eyes check” at the conclusion of [[onboarding]].<ref>You won’t.</ref> Less so when Briggs J catches them for you in a judgment from the commercial division of the High Court.<ref>He will.</ref>
Party-specific labels are only needed once the studied symmetry of the Master Agreement gives way to the need, articulated in in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} and {{isdaprov|Confirmation}}s, to stipulate who is taking which side on a given trade, giving which covenant or submitting to which {{isdaprov|Additional Termination Event}}.  


==== “BINO” — bilateral in name only ====
The parties may be equals, but we still need to know who is going to pay the [[fixed rate]] and who the [[Floating rate|floating]]; which thresholds, maxima, minima, covenants, details, agents and terms apply to which party. This much is necessarily different. Nothing beyond: the {{isdama}} assumes you already know who is who, having agreed it in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}}.
{{Smallcaps|But there is}} a better objection: for all our automatic protestations to the contrary, the ISDA is not ''really'' a symmetrical contract of equals. It ''is'' often a financing contract, in economic effect, even if not in formal structure. Where one party is an [[end user|customer]] gaining exposure to a market risk and the other is a dealer providing [[Delta hedge|delta-hedged]] exposure to that risk, a swap is a sort of “[[synthetic loan]]”.


Realising this may change how you think about ISDA negotiation. This thought grew and grew and now there is a [[A swap as a loan|whole new article about it]].
So we agree: for this swap trading relationship we will call you “Party B”, and me “Party A”. Beyond these colourless labels, we are equal.


But except for that a class of [[Inter-dealer|inter-dealer]] swap relationships, {{isdama}}s are “bilateral” only really in ''name'': one party — the [[swap dealer]], provides exposures to another, the customer, who consumes them. The customer is, economically, a principal: it provides the impulse to trade; it elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The [[dealer]] is, economically even if not legally, an agent: it hedges, calculates values and is burdened with additional [[regulatory capital]] charges if it doesn’t get its [[close-out netting]] right.  
But they are maddeningly forgettable labels: harking from a time where the idea of “find and replace all” in an electronic document seemed like [[Tipp-Ex]]-denying, devilish magic. It might have been easier — and saved some curial angst— had parties been able to use ''unique'' identifying labels across their agreement portfolios.  


This has led to two kinds of bother: first, a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since [[swap dealer]]s set up their templates to assume ''they'' will be Party A and their customers Party B, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can spark an unseemly dispute from which the dealer will inevitably have to back down. At least one swap dealer solved this problem by deciding to be “Party B” as standard. This only confused clients who were unused to being “Party A”.
{{Quote|It was, I am afraid, a rather sloppily drafted document. First, it described LBIE as Party A and LBF as Party B, contrary to the Schedule which gave them the opposite descriptions.
 
:—Briggs, J, in ''Lehman Brothers International (Europe) v. Lehman Brothers Finance S.A.'' [2012] EWHC 1072 (Ch)}}
Furthermore, when labouring over some neatly [[iatrogenic]] [[co-calculation agent]] fallback dispute mechanism — and be assured, you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by your reward for it, in heaven or on earth — it is easy to get your “[[Party A]]s” and “[[Party B]]s” mixed up. Doing so buries, deep in the [[fossil record]], a technical deficiency that may go entirely unrecognised for ''decades''.
 
Roll forward eighteen years. The world is again on the brink of financial [[Apocalypse]]. The customer is now a [[systemically important financial institution|systemically-important]] leviathan, largely thanks to years of optimistically lax credit sanctioning. But suddenly, it is teetering. The [[Credit officer|chief credit officer]] runs about with her hair on fire and for the first time, ''everyone is staring forensically at the docs''. Suddenly that co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism is all that stands between the firm and a three billion dollar abyss. And guess what? ''Some clot transposed “Party A” and “Party B”''.
 
====The real distinction: [[dealer]] and [[customer]]====
{{smallcaps|Beyond that small}} class of [[inter-dealer]] swap contracts that make up a [[dealer]]’s funding and hedging programme — there ''is'' a material distinction between the parties to an swap contract.<ref>Almost all {{isdama}}s will be between a ''customer'' and a ''dealer''. A few will be [[inter-dealer]] — but there are only so many dealers. Almost ''none'' will be inter-customer. I know, I know: the first ever swap was, though, right?</ref> The asymmetry comes not from whether one is [[long]] or [[short]], or buyer or seller, but from who is ''customer'' and who is ''dealer''.
 
A customer or “[[end user]]” uses the {{isdama}} to ''change'' its absolute exposure to a given risk or underlier. To take, or lay off, a risk.
 
A [[dealer]] uses the {{isdama}} to earn a [[commission]]. It does this, yes, by providing its customers a changed absolute exposure, but at the same time carefully hedges that exposure so that, but for those fees, the dealer is market ''flat''. Now, it is the nature of the beast that a dealer can’t always ''stay'' market flat: it is too dependent upon the performance of its customers, counterparties and models for that — but this is not for want of trying.
 
====Why does it matter?====
{{smallcaps|What is in}} a name?
 
This may be to draw a long bow, but you could argue that emphasising bilaterality has led the regulatory dance into the wrong corner of the dancefloor. The JC does.
 
The logic is this: this is a contract of equals. Each poses an equal, but offsetting, risk to the other. Therefore credit concern cuts both ways, so any regulatory impositions should — ''must'' — also apply both ways.
 
And so we have seen: [[swap dealer]]s have to post [[Regulatory initial margin|regulatory initial]] and [[Variation margin|variation margin]] to their customers, just the same way their customers must post it to them.
 
''But this is nuts''. Swap dealers are regulated financial institutions providing a service for a fixed commission. When dealing they don’t take on outright market positions. They must hold [[regulatory capital]] against their dealing activity. That this means of managing systemic risk hasn’t always ''worked'' fabulously well is not the point: the principle is sensible: ensure financial institutions are sound by obliging them to ''hold on'' to money, rather than making them give it away.
 
And a customer who frets about its outsized exposure to a dealer has a ready solution: ''move its business away''. Diversifying the portfolio encourages competition in the market and introduces a healthy redundancy.<ref>In “[[Normal Accidents: Living with High-Risk Technologies|normal accidents]]” terminology financial markets are [[Tight coupling|tightly-coupled]], [[Complexity|non-linear]] systems where “slack” loosens that coupling and reduces the risk of catastrophic failure.</ref> Overall, encouraging customers to limit their outright exposure to dealers enhances the market’s overall resilience.
 
Obliging dealers to [[Variation margin|cash-collateralise]] customers’ open positions creates the ''opposite'' incentives. Customers are encouraged not to diversify their risk, but to concentrate it, with the [[dealer]]s offering the most aggressive margin rates. And the dealer market is competitive to the point of being paranoid, as we learned from [[Archegos]]. Dealers will cut their required margins to the bone, thereby increasing their risk of loss.
 
By contrast, [[end user]]s are not regulated. They are often thinly capitalised funds, trading with leverage on someone else’s money: guess who? ''The [[dealer]]''.
 
The real source of systemic [[dealer]] risk is the [[Second-order derivative|second-order risk]] presented by the dealer’s ''customers'' blowing up.


This is a situation a [[dealer]] is more likely to get itself into if it has had to pay away wodges of [[regulatory margin]] to collateralise its customer’s un-realised gains, giving those customers, already betting with the broker’s money, even more of it. We have a separate essay on this: See ''[[when variation margin attacks]]''.
Being ''so'' generic, the “Party A” and “Party B” labels can lead to practical difficulties: a [[dealer]] with thirty thousand counterparties wants to be “Party A” every time, just for peace of mind and literary continuity when perusing its collection of Schedules, as we know [[dealer]]s on occasion are minded to do.<ref>They are not.</ref> This is not just a matter of having to play in your “away strip” every now and then: if, here and there, a dealer must be “Party B”, having lost the toss to a counterparty who also insists on being Party A, this can lead to anxious moments, should one have momentarily forgotten the switch during the negotiation and assigned your carefully-argued infinite [[IM]] {{csaprov|Threshold}} to the other guy.


Might the market have gravitated this way were it not for our fiction of pretending this is a bilateral relationship?
Frights like this are quite energising, if you pick them up during the “four eyes check” at the conclusion of [[onboarding]].<ref>You won’t.</ref> Less so, when Briggs J catches them for you when handing down a judgment from the commercial division of the High Court.<ref>He will.</ref>