The curious structure of an MTN: Difference between revisions

Replaced content with "{{essay|repack|MTN structure|{{layman|bond}}}}"
No edit summary
(Replaced content with "{{essay|repack|MTN structure|{{layman|bond}}}}")
Tag: Replaced
 
(18 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|repack|{{layman|bond}}}}You will know old Grandpa Contrarian’s story of [[the farmer and the sheep]]. It is illustrated richly in every cove, inlet and waterway of the financial markets, but is no better exemplified than in the genetic structure of a [[medium term note]] programme.
{{essay|repack|MTN structure|{{layman|bond}}}}
 
These, for the fortunately uninitiated, are architectural structures by which corporations raise funds in the international [[debt capital market]]s. Their history is long and mildly diverting at best — the type who naturally deals in debt instruments is not really given to intrigue — but for our purposes it is important.
 
=== Conceptual underpinnings ===
Now: as per the panel summary, a [[bond]] of any kind is an [[IOU]], in that it represents an entitlement to be repaid a loan. In earlier epochs one would borrow against a “note” — literally, a signed piece of paper indicating your preparedness to pay a sum to whoever presented it, in exchange for its surrender.
 
The neat thing about this kind of note is its transferability: the original lender can “[[negotiability|negotiate]]” it — sell it<ref>Or pledge, or lend it.</ref> without the issuer’s permission, or even knowledge — and its value will be the [[present value]] of the issuer’s promise to pay. A note is a unilateral contract, therefore. A conventional loan is a ''bilateral'' contract, and the job of transferring ones rights and liabilities under it is more involved, and often requires the cooperation of the borrower.
 
The other neat thing about notes compared to loans is that you can easily divide a big borrowing into lots of little notes, rather than a single big one. Thus, you can access a wider pool of lenders — including [[Belgian dentist]]<nowiki/>s, as we will see — each of whom can manage its own exposure without reference to the others, by buying or selling bonds in the secondary market.
 
Notes therefore are more liquid, transferable things, and while they are outstanding the issuer need not even know who its creditors are: they hove into view only upon payment of [[principal]] or [[interest]], when they would show up at the issuer’s office with their instrument in hand.
 
=== Industrialisation of debt securities ===
This all being the case, notes quickly became popular, and the process of issuing, selling and maintaining them industrialised. Notes were “security printed”, like banknotes. [[Interest]] payments were represented by perforated [[Coupon|coupons]] that could be detached and presented (or “stripped” and separately traded): for a long-dated bond, where there wasn’t room for all the coupons, there would be “[[talon]]s” attached entitling the bearer to a fresh strip of coupons. Issuers appointed banks as “[[paying agent]]s” to handle the mechanics of dealing with holders, paying out on presentation and so on. In some jurisdictions<ref>America being a prime example, thanks to the glorious strictures of the [[Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act]] ([[TEFRA]]) of 1982, which introduced punitive tax treatment for bearer bonds, on the grounds that they were inherently fishy, income-sheltering things — a quality that never bothered the Belgian dental profession in the same way.</ref> issuers needed to maintain a record of noteholders, so created “registered” notes which were profoundly different in legal ''concept'' — title transferred by entry in the register, whereas with a [[bearer instrument]] the security itself ''was'' the debt and title passed by delivery — and there needed to be terms to deal with certain unwanted contingencies: replacing lost or mutilated notes; provisions for noteholder meetings to consider amendments to terms and so on.
 
Now an [[IOU]] is a simple enough thing: the legal architecture making it all possible was another thing altogether: [[trust deed]]<nowiki/>s, paying agency agreements, [[dealer]] agreements, [[prospectus]]<nowiki/>es and so on, and the up-front cost of a “stand-alone” debt issuance was formidable. Thus emerged the [[medium term note programme]] — a pre-crafted architecture containing all the standard terms, appointments and so on, which an issuer could quickly “tap” when it needed to, in a fraction of the time and cost.
 
In parallel the information revolution arrived and notes started to trade electronically, in a [[clearing system]]<ref>In the European markets, there are two major [[clearing system]]s: [[Euroclear]] and [[Clearstream]].</ref>. Here noteholders’ interests were represented as electronic entries in their clearing system accounts there was no need for security printing, perforated coupons, a wide network of paying agents, and the identity for the time being of the holders was ascertainable, at least by the clearing system, which had to maintain the records on order to ensure everyone got paid. At the very heart there was still a physically printed note: just one: a “global note”, representing all the nominally issued notes, held by a “[[common depositary]]” — a custodian for the electronic clearing systems in which the notes are traded.
 
=== Residual DNA ===
By the 1990s, all notes, bonds and other securities were electronically cleared, and none has been security printed since. Nonetheless, the MTN terms and structure still bear traces of their physical biology, a bit like tailbones, appendixes and male nipples. The basic rationale is “well, the [[clearing system]]s might not work one day — you know, there could be some kind of post-apocalyptic, Mad Max-style future with everyone driving round in battle trucks and drinking their own urine — so I might need to change these into security-printed definitive notes, so we better leave these terms in just in case”.
 
Now the [[JC]] would be the last one to pooh-pooh the idea of a dystopian future — given the last few years he rather expects it at some stage, in fact — but, really: if you are eating caterpillars, presenting your coupons to the Luxembourg paying agent is going to be a long way down your list of priorities.
 
In any case, this useless DNA makes for a great deal more complicatedness than, in practice one really needs. Your bond terms and conditions have to deal with the following:
 
* [[Registered security|Registered]] or [[Bearer security|bearer]] form
* [[Clearing system|Electronically cleared]] or [[Definitive security|definitive]]
* Where definitive and bearer, mechanics of presenting coupons, talons and so on.
 
===The logical structure of legal documents===
This leads us on to [[Semantic code project|one of our pet interests]]: why are legal documents so convoluted, and what can one do to correct it. For this we need to delve into the underlying logical structure of a contract.
 
Any legal statement, however [[Fish Principle|Fish]]ily articulated, boils down to a basic logical proposition, rather like software code, with propositions, conditions, logic gates, if/then statements, and so on, only we call them definitions, obligations, rights, discretions, options and so on.
 
Any logic gate — in legal language, an alternative, choice or option, increases the inherent complicatedness of a proposition.
 
Take this statement about cricket and rugby balls:
{{tabletopflex|100}}
{{cellwidth|100}}
 
<small>{{subtable|
A ball: <br>
(a) if it is red
:(i) if it is round
::(A) may not be used for rugby
::(B) may be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
:(ii) if it is oval:
::(A) may be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
(b) if it is white:
:(i) if it is round:
::(A) may not be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may be used for one-day cricket
:(ii) if it is oval:
::(A) may be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
}}</small>
Or you could render it thus:
<small>{{subtable|
An oval ball: <br>
:(i) may be used for rugby
:(ii) may not be used for cricket
A round ball:
:(i) may not be used for rugby
:(ii) if it is red:
::(a) may be used for test cricket
:::(b) may not be used for one-day cricket
:(iii) if it is white:
::(a) may not be used for test cricket
:::(b) may be used for one-day cricket
}}</small>
Or how about:
<small>{{subtable|
Rugby must be played with an oval ball <br>
Test cricket must be played with a round red ball <br>
One-day cricket must be played with a round white ball <br>
}}</small>
 
{{tb}}
 
{{sa}}
 
* [[Medium term note programme]]
* [[Repackaging programme]]
{{Ref}}