When variation margin attacks: Difference between revisions

no edit summary
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 45: Line 45:


==== Intermediaries ====
==== Intermediaries ====
There are lots of types of intermediary: those who comprise market infrastructure: [[Exchange|stock exchange]]s, [[clearing system]]s, securities depositories and so on; those who earn only a [[commission]] from their involvement, and take no [[principal]] risk<ref>I include here “[[quasi-agent]]” roles that are conducted on a [[riskless principal]], but (absent insolvency) are economically neutral: thse participants are remunerated by [[commission]] or fixed [[mark-up]] and do not have “[[Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life - Book Review|skin in the game]]”.</ref>: [[Cash brokerage|cash broker]]<nowiki/>s, [[Investment manager|investment managers]], [[Clearing broker|clearer]]<nowiki/>s, [[Market-maker|market-makers]] and [[Intermediate broker|intermediate brokers]]; and those who ''do'' take principal risk, but only by lending to their customers, and generally don’t participate in the upside or downside<ref>Barring through “gap loss” where, due to portfolio losses, the customer is insolvent and cannot repay its loan.</ref> of the investments they are financing: [[Bank|banks]].  
There are lots of types of intermediary: those who comprise market infrastructure: [[Exchange|stock exchange]]s, [[clearing system]]s, securities depositories and so on; those who earn only a [[commission]] from their involvement, and take no [[principal]] risk<ref>I include here “[[quasi-agent]]” roles that are conducted on a [[riskless principal]], but (absent insolvency) are economically neutral: thse participants are remunerated by [[commission]] or fixed [[mark-up]] and do not have “[[Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life - Book Review|skin in the game]]”.</ref>: [[Cash brokerage|cash broker]]<nowiki/>s, [[Investment manager|investment managers]], [[Clearing broker|clearer]]<nowiki/>s, [[Market-maker|market-makers]] and [[Intermediate broker|intermediate brokers]]; and those who ''do'' take principal risk, but only by lending to their customers, and generally don’t participate in the upside or downside<ref>Barring through “gap loss” where, due to portfolio losses, the customer is insolvent and cannot repay its loan.</ref> of the investments they are financing: [[Bank|banks]].


All of these intermediaries have one thing in common: their remuneration does not depend on how their customer’s investments perform.<ref>Unless they perform ''so'' badly they cause the customer’s bankruptcy.</ref> Intermediaries do not have [[Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life - Book Review|skin in the game]]. They are not supposed to lose ''any'' money, let alone billions of dollars of the stuff.
All of these intermediaries have one thing in common: their remuneration does not depend on how their customer’s investments perform.<ref>Unless they perform ''so'' badly they cause the customer’s bankruptcy.</ref> Intermediaries do not have [[Skin in the Game: Hidden Asymmetries in Daily Life - Book Review|skin in the game]]. They are not supposed to lose ''any'' money, let alone billions of dollars of the stuff.
Line 58: Line 58:
=='''The multi-coloured swap shop'''==
=='''The multi-coloured swap shop'''==
[[File:Noel.png|right|frameless]]
[[File:Noel.png|right|frameless]]
The [[swap  history|history of swaps]] is interesting and fairly well-documented. It all started in earnest in 1981, with a bright idea [[Salomon Brothers]] had to match up IBM, who needed U.S. dollars but had a load of Swiss francs and Deutschmarks, with the World Bank, which had all the dollars anyone could need but needed to meet obligations in CHF and DEM which it wasn’t able to borrow. The two institutions “swapped” their debts, exchanging dollars for the European currencies and paying coupons on them, with an agreement to return the the same values of the respective currencies at maturity.
The [[swap  history|history of swaps]] is interesting and fairly well-documented. It all started in earnest in 1981, with a bright idea [[Salomon Brothers]] had to match up IBM, who needed U.S. dollars but had a load of Swiss francs and Deutschmarks, with the World Bank, which had all the dollars anyone could need but needed to meet obligations in CHF and DEM which it wasn’t able to borrow. The two institutions “swapped” their debts, exchanging dollars for the European currencies and paying [[coupon]]<nowiki/>s on them, with an agreement to return the the same values of the respective currencies at maturity.


Everyone else recognised this to be a cool idea, and before you know it, swaps trading was a trillion dollar industry. Okay; this took a bit of time, but in the geological history of finance from the time of Hammurabi, it was the blink of an eye. But anyway, note a few things:
Everyone else recognised this to be a cool idea, and before you know it, swaps trading was a trillion dollar industry. Okay; this took a bit of time, but in the geological history of finance from the time of Hammurabi, it was the blink of an eye. But anyway, note a few things:


Unlike traditional banking activity, swap transactions are bilateral.  In one sense, ''both'' parties were lending to each other — hence they were not just parties, but “''counter''parties”.<ref>Or maybe this just means they sat at a counter. This has just occurred to me. Why not? These are [[OTC|over-the-counter]] derivatives, after all.</ref>  In another sense, ''neither'' was: as long as you could [[Set-Off|offset]] the swapped loans, at inception a swap trade was market neutral.<ref>Law students will know this notion of enforceable set-off is a tricky one, especially if you are trading across international markets, where insolvency regimes are capricious, and might struggle to understand it, in a way they tended not to struggle with ordinary secured lending. Hence the great, tedious topic of [[Close-out netting|netting]], which isn’t wildly germane to this essay except to point out that [[Credit risk mitigation|credit mitigation]] for swaps by set-off, not security, and credit risk can swing around, depending on the market value of the underlying obligations.</ref>  
Unlike traditional banking activity, swap transactions are ''bilateral''.  In one sense, ''both'' parties were lending to each other — hence they were not just parties, but “''counter''parties”.<ref>Or maybe this just means they sat at a counter. This has just occurred to me. Why not? These are [[OTC|over-the-counter]] derivatives, after all.</ref>  In another sense, ''neither'' was: as long as you could [[Set-Off|offset]] the swapped loans, at inception a swap trade was market neutral: each “lent” the other something of equal value.<ref>Law students will know this notion of enforceable set-off is a tricky one, especially if you are trading across international markets, where insolvency regimes are capricious, and might struggle to understand it, in a way they tended not to struggle with ordinary secured lending. Hence the great, tedious topic of [[Close-out netting|netting]], which isn’t wildly germane to this essay except to point out that [[Credit risk mitigation|credit mitigation]] for swaps by set-off, not security, and credit risk can swing around, depending on the market value of the underlying obligations.</ref>  


But a swap does not ''stay'' neutral. Its [[mark-to-market]] value will change, and can swing around. Depending on how the cross-rates move, ''either'' party can be owed money. Hence the concept of “[[moneyness]]”: either party could be [[in-the-money]] or [[out-of-the-money]].  
But the respective values of those lent “somethings” do not stay put, and so the economic profile of a swap — being the [[prevailing value]] of one of those “somethings” minus the [[prevailing value]] of the other — does not ''stay'' neutral. Its [[mark-to-market]] value” will change. Depending on how the cross-rates move, ''either'' party can be owed money. Hence, the concept of “[[moneyness]]”: on any day, either party to a swap can be [[in-the-money]]”  — if the “something” it owes the other party is smaller than the “something”  the other party owes it — or [[out-of-the-money]], if it owes more than it is due.  


This was quite a different thing, and it really challenged the regulatory philosophy of financial services regulation. Until now, there had always  been an intermediary and a customer, and you always knew who was who: the intermediary was authorised, regulated to provide its services and appropriately capitalised ''to protect the customer'';<ref>And its depositors: also customers.</ref> the customer didn’t need to be regulated as it the intermediary could obviously look after itself.
This whole idea of “moneyness”, and either party potentially being owed money, was quite a new thing, and it really challenged the philosophy of financial services regulation. Until now, there had always  been an intermediary and a customer, and you always knew who was who: the intermediary was authorised, regulated to provide its services and appropriately capitalised ''to protect the customer'';<ref>And its depositors: also customers.</ref> the customer didn’t need to be regulated as it the intermediary could obviously look after itself.


The evolution of swaps challenged that: now either party could be creditor or debtor. It was hard to know who to regulate. Who needed protecting from whom? Did they ''both'' have to be regulated? Or ''neither''? For the first couple of decades, the regulatory answer was basically “neither”.<ref name="fwmd">Hence widespread allusions to the wild west, [[Locust|locusts]], [[Black swan|black swans]], casino banking, [[financial weapons of mass destruction]] and so on.</ref>
Swaps challenged all that: now ''either'' party could be creditor or debtor. It was hard to know who to regulate. Who needed protecting from whom? Did they ''both'' have to be regulated? Or ''neither''? For the first couple of decades, the answer was basically “neither”.<ref name="fwmd">Hence widespread allusions to the wild west, [[Locust|locusts]], [[Black swan|black swans]], casino banking, [[financial weapons of mass destruction]] and so on.</ref>


==== Intermediaries, redux ====
==== Intermediaries, redux ====
So, the clarity about who was an intermediary broke down a little. Swaps were a financial product in which there did not necessarily need to be an intermediary at all: the very first swap, between IBM and the World Bank, was effectively a transaction between two customers, in that each took principal risk to the transaction. And there is an entire realm of swap trades ''between'' intermediaries, where neither side is a “customer” as such.  
So, the clarity about who was an intermediary broke down a little. Swaps did not necessarily need an intermediary at all, though in practice these days there usually is one: the very first swap, between IBM and the World Bank, was between two customers, or “[[end-user]]<nowiki/>s”, in that each took principal risk to the transaction. And there is an entire realm of swap trades ''between'' intermediaries, where neither side is a “customer” as such.  


But the huge preponderance of swap volume is between an [[intermediary]] — a “[[swap dealer]]” — and a [[customer]] — indelicately described as an “[[end-user]]”. So are [[swap dealer|swap dealers]] intermediaries in the traditional sense, having no “skin in the game”? In one sense, no: being a principal to the swap contract, the [[swap dealer|dealer]] takes the other side of the trade to its customer, and is fully exposed to the [[underlier]]’s performance. But in another sense, it ''is'' an intermediary: [[swap dealer]]<nowiki/>s generally [[Delta-hedging|delta-hedge]] their risk. In many cases are prohibited by regulation from taking proprietary positions.<ref>This is the famous “Volcker Rule”.</ref> In the classic case of equity swaps, the dealer executes a physical trade in the cash market, holds or finances that position, and prices its swap at exactly that price. It has no net exposure to the trade at all. Economically, it is no different from a broker lending on margin.
But the huge preponderance of swap volume is between an [[intermediary]] — a “[[swap dealer]]” — on one side and a [[customer]] — on the other.  
 
So, are [[swap dealer|swap dealers]] “intermediaries” in the traditional sense, having no “skin in the game”? In one sense, no: being a principal to the swap contract, the [[swap dealer|dealer]] takes the other side of the trade to its customer, and is fully exposed to the [[underlier]]’s performance. But in another sense, yes: it ''is'' an intermediary: [[swap dealer]]<nowiki/>s generally [[Delta-hedging|delta-hedge]] their risk. In many cases are prohibited by regulation from taking proprietary positions.<ref>This is the famous “Volcker Rule”.</ref> In the classic case of equity swaps, the dealer executes a physical trade in the cash market, holds or finances that position, and prices its swap at exactly that price. It has no net exposure to the trade at all. Economically, it is no different from a broker lending on margin.


==== Deregulation and electronic trading ====
==== Deregulation and electronic trading ====
Line 85: Line 87:


==== Netting ====
==== Netting ====
We are not really concerned with netting here — the [[JC]] has plenty to say on that topic [[Close-out netting|elsewhere]] — so let’s quickly deal with it: just as you could offset the [[present value]] of the opposing legs of each swap to calculate a positive or negative [[mark-to-market]] value for that swap, so too could you offset positive and negative [[mark-to-market]] values for different swaps to arrive at a single net exposure for your whole {{isdama}}. This idea — [[close-out netting]] — was a stroke of genius, and the brave commandos of {{icds}} encoded this “[[single agreement]]” concept into the {{1987ma}} and its successors.  
We are not really concerned with netting here — the [[JC]] has plenty to say on that topic [[Close-out netting|elsewhere]] — so let’s quickly deal with it: just as you could offset the [[present value]] of the opposing ''legs'' of each transaction to calculate a positive or negative [[mark-to-market]] value for that swap, so too could you offset positive and negative [[mark-to-market]] values for different swap transactions to arrive at a single net exposure for your whole {{isdama}}. This idea — [[close-out netting]] — was a stroke of genius, and the brave commandos of {{icds}} encoded this “[[single agreement]]” concept into the {{1987ma}} and its successors. Giving effect to netting contracts, and attaining the capital relief they promise is now a multi-million-dollar industry.  


==== Credit support ====
==== Credit support ====
But even with netting, the highly [[Leverage|levered]] nature of swap transactions meant that one’s overall net exposure could swing around wildly.
But even with netting, the [[Leverage|levered]] nature of swap transactions means that your overall net exposure can still swing around wildly.
 
In 1994 ISDA released a “[[credit support annex]]” to the {{isdama}} under which the parties could exchange “credit support” to offset their respective net exposures. This is all rather complicated and fiddly<ref>See our [[CSA Anatomy]], for as much detail as any one person could want.</ref> but the gist of it is that you calculate your net [[exposure]] under an {{Isdama}} on any day and, if it is over an agreed threshold, you can require your counterparty “post” you cash or securities as collateral for that exposure. If the exposure then swings back towards your counterparty tomorrow, it can require you to return equivalent assets . Rinse and repeat.
 
This is rather neat, because it “zeroes out” each party’s [[credit exposure]] to the other each day.
 
Like the {{Isdama}}, the [[CSA]] is a bilateral document: it assumes the parties are equal, arm’s-length counterparties and that each can post to the other. In the early days, [[Swap dealer|swap dealers]] often adjusted their CSAs so that only the customer posted credit support. This made sense, since end-users of swaps tend not to be prudentially regulated and therefore are not heavily capitalised, whereas intermediaries and swap dealers usually are. What is more, over this period, the [[Basel Accords]] published increasingly stringent and detailed rules<ref>Basel I was 30 pages. Basel II, published June 2006 (whoops!) was 347 pages. Basel III, as of September 2021, is 1626 pages.</ref> about how much capital banks should hold against their trading exposures to their customers.  


A solution arrived a decade or so after swap trading started in earnest. In 1994 ISDA released a “[[credit support annex]]” to the {{isdama}} under which the parties could exchange “credit support” to each other to offset their prevailing exposures to each other. This is all rather complicated and fiddly<ref>See our [[CSA Anatomy]], for as much detail as any one person could want.</ref> but the gist of it was that you could calculate your net [[exposure]] to your counterparty on any day and, if it was over an agreed threshold, you could require your counterparty “post” cash, bonds or liquid securities to you as collateral for that exposure. If the exposure swung back, the counterparty could require you to return those assets tomorrow. Rinse and repeat.
If at first customers were less bothered about the creditworthiness of their swap dealers,<ref>To be sure, sophisticated investment managers were already requiring their dealers post [[variation margin]] by the the start of the new millennium.</ref> this all changed, fast, during the 2008 financial crisis in which every major dealer had at least a near-death experience, and a number — [[Lehman]], Merrill Lynch, Bear Stearns, and literally dozens of others<ref>This is a [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_banks_acquired_or_bankrupted_during_the_Great_Recession fun list].</ref> had actual ones.


Like the {{Isdama}}, the [[CSA]] is a bilateral document: it assumes the parties are equal, arm’s-length counterparties and that each can post to the other. In the early days, [[Swap dealer|swap dealers]] often adjusted their CSAs so that only the customer posted credit support. Over this period, the [[Basel Accords]] published increasingly stringent and detailed rules<ref>Basel I was 30 pages. Basel II, published June 2006 (whoops!) was 347 pages. Basel III, as of September 2021, is 1626 pages.</ref> about how much capital banks should hold against their trading exposures to their customers. If at first customers were less bothered about the creditworthiness of their swap dealers,<ref>To be sure, sophisticated investment managers were already requiring their dealers post [[variation margin]] by the the start of the new millennium.</ref> this all changed, fast, during the 2008 financial crisis in which every major dealer had at least a near-death experience, if not an actual one.
Suddenly the dealers, themselves were a source of systemic risk.  


Suddenly the dealers, themselves, were a source of systemic risk. The regulatory reform machine moved into overdrive; the era of unregulated derivatives was over. Regulators the world over began requiring all swap counterparties to collect [[variation margin]] on all common forms of swap contract: bilateral, daily, and in [[Cash|''cash'']].
The regulatory reform machine moved into overdrive; the era of unregulated derivatives was over. Regulators the world over began requiring ''all'' swap counterparties, prudentially regulated or not, to provide [[variation margin]] on all common forms of swap contract: bilateral, daily, and in [[Cash|''cash'']].


===== Remember the good old days =====
===== Remember the good old days =====
Now remember that old distinction between intermediary and customer. Intermediaries are meant to be well-capitalised; they don’t have a dog in the fight: their interest is just in collecting their commission. Their customers take the market risks.
Now remember that old distinction between “intermediary” and “customer”. Intermediaries are meant to be well-capitalised; they don’t have a dog in the fight: their interest is just in collecting their commission. Their customers take the market risks.


Swap dealers ''look'' like they are taking market risks, but they are not. Post Volcker, they are not ''allowed'' to. Swap dealers are passing on the return of their hedging activity to their customers, and collecting commissions and interest on financing.<ref>We have in mind [[Synthetic equity swap|synthetic equity derivatives]] here. This may be less clearly the case in other asset classes, but it is still (post Volcker) broadly true for all of them.</ref>
Swap dealers ''look'' like they are taking market risks, but they are not. Post Volcker, they are not ''allowed'' to. Swap dealers are passing on the return of their hedging activity to their customers, and collecting commissions and interest on financing.<ref>We have in mind [[Synthetic equity swap|synthetic equity derivatives]] here. This may be less clearly the case in other asset classes, but it is still (post Volcker) broadly true for all of them.</ref> They are somewhat at the mercy of their customers: having put positions on, their legal rights to terminate them again tend to be legally and [[Commercial imperative|commercially]] circumscribed. Customers can terminate at any time — it’s their investment — and for any reason, including vague nervousness about the solvency of their dealer.


You can, and physical [[prime brokerage]] customers do, achieve exactly the same effect with a margin loan: the customer buys shares on margin; the [[prime broker]] holds the shares as collateral for the loan. If the shares decline in value, the broker may call for more margin. If the shares rise in value, the customer generates increased equity with the broker, but is not automatically entitled to the cash value of that equity. There is no variation margin, as such.
===== Physical prime brokerage =====
You can, and physical [[prime brokerage]] customers do, achieve exactly the same effect with a [[Margin lending|margin loan]]: the customer buys shares on margin; the [[prime broker]] holds the shares as collateral for the loan. If the shares decline in value, the broker may call for more margin. If the shares rise in value, the customer generates increased equity with the broker, but is not automatically entitled to the cash value of that equity. There is no variation margin, as such.


The prime broker may ''agree'' to lend more against that equity — that is the business it is in, after all — but it is not ''obliged'' to.  The customer cannot force the broker to lend against the equity. As long as it leaves enough equity in the account the customer may withdraw excess equity, but only by taking the shares it owns. Withdrawing ''shares'' from a prime brokerage account doesn’t fundamentally change ones debtor/creditor relationship. Withdrawing cash ''against'' shares assuredly does.
But here is the difference: the [[prime broker]] may ''agree'' to lend more against that equity — that is the business it is in, after all — but it is not ''obliged'' to.  The customer cannot force the broker to lend against the equity. As long as it leaves enough equity in the account the customer may withdraw excess equity, but only by taking the shares it owns. Withdrawing ''shares'' from a prime brokerage account doesn’t fundamentally change ones debtor/creditor relationship. Withdrawing cash ''against'' shares assuredly does.


Now: because a synthetic swap position looks like a bilateral derivative — okay, okay: ''is'' a bilateral derivative — it is regulated as such, and is in scope for mandatory variation margin. ''Both'' sides are obliged to post [[VM]], every day, where they are [[out-of-the-money]]. Whenever a customer makes any positive return on an [[equity swap]], its swap dealer is, technically, [[out-of-the-money]], and must therefore post [[variation margin]] to the value of that positive return.
Now: because a synthetic swap position looks like a bilateral derivative — okay, okay: ''is'' a bilateral derivative — it is regulated as such, and is in scope for mandatory variation margin. ''Both'' sides are obliged to post [[VM]], every day, where they are [[out-of-the-money]]. Whenever a customer makes any positive return on an [[equity swap]], its swap dealer is, technically, [[out-of-the-money]], and must therefore post [[variation margin]] to the value of that positive return.