Mediocrity drift

Revision as of 13:43, 21 December 2022 by Amwelladmin (talk | contribs)
The Human Resources military-industrial complex
The instrument (the “telescreen”, it was called) could be dimmed, but there was no way of shutting it off completely.
Index: Click to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

Mediocrity drift
/ˌmiːdɪˈɒkrɪti drɪft/ (n.)
A curious, unintended, negative feedback loop of lazy human capital management.

Let’s say firms, when presented with broadly equivalent candidates, prioritise those of a type it doesn’t have when hiring, and those of which it has too many when selecting candidates for a RIF. For those who value cognitive diversity, let alone cultural diversity, stands to reason.

Since one tends to hire one golden strand at a time, but reduce the workforce in large hanks, this creates an odd system effect, predicated on three general assumptions:

  • Staff with the gumption to leave tend to be relatively good employees.
  • Conversely: those who aren’t much chop — who are already overpaid for what they do — are tend not to quit, because they are onto a good thing, would need to find an even more gullible employer to hire them: consequently they will only leave if you make them, by performance management or through a RIF.
  • That all personnel, however you categorise them, are evenly distributed relative to the cost-value threshold, and that any given subgroup, however classified (except by reference to pure value) will be about as good as any other.

So, IT professionals as a group will be as good at what they do as will lawyers; young as well as old, men as women, and so on. Each group — IT pros, legal eagles, the young, the old, men, women — will within their own group have broadly similar distributions of outperformers and plodders.

If so, then a system which favours one group (group A) over another (group B) has a counterintuitive effect on the remaining populations of both groups: on average, the unfavoured group will increase in relative value, and the favoured group will decrease in relative value, even though no individual performance, in either group, changes at all.

On a second glance, you can see why this should be so. The process systematically weeds out underperforming members of group B and overperforming members of group A. The “good” side of the distribution will progressively become group B-dominated — they are not being bid away as frequently — and the “below par” section will becomes progressively group A dominated, as poor performing group B members are selected for eradication.

Two observations: firstly, here is systemantics in its raw natural state; and secondly, notice how pernicious the idea of the average is here.

On average, the group A is paid progressively less. It looks like group A members are being systematically discriminated against on pay, but this is not so (in this model, no-one’s pay changes) in fact group A members are being favoured for poor performance.

How your incoming lateral hires perform will remain to be seen but, remember, performance is measured relative to cost. Since by leaving they have marked themselves to market, overperformers leave their old slot in the quincunx where they were at the top, and enter their new quincunx at the median. The vicissitudes of random chance mean the new arrivals might wind up in any slot but, in any case, their slot on average will be normally distributed. Your arriving at a higher cost than the ones you are replacing, they start not as outlier good staff, but average ones.

See also