Bilaterality: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Created page with "{{a|isda|}}Unlike many financing documents, the {{isdama}} eschews understandable terms for its participants — ones that help you orient who is who: you know, like “Borrow..."
 
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|isda|}}Unlike many financing documents, the {{isdama}} eschews understandable terms for its participants — ones that help you orient who is who: you know, like “Borrower” and “Lender”; “Bank” and “Client”; or “Buyer” and “Seller” — for the decidedly more gnomic “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.  
{{a|isda|}}Unlike many financing documents, the {{isdama}} eschews understandable terms for its participants — ones that help you orient who is who: you know, like “Borrower” and “Lender”; “Bank” and “Client”; or “Buyer” and “Seller” — for the decidedly more gnomic “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.  
===Etymology===
This derives from a working theory that gripped the [[First Men]] as they forged the [[deep magic]] that become the [[First ISDA]]: “a swap contract,” they intoned, “is an equal opportunity sort of an affair; Biblically, righteous in that one is neither a lender nor a borrower under it, but a ''counterparty''”. A counterparty is [[cunisian]]: neither one thing nor the other, but infused with glorious ''possibilities''. Either fellow may owe or be owed; each has, in theory, the same likelihood as the other of being ''[[in-the-money|in]]'' or ''[[out-of-the-money]]''. This is a bilateral relationship.
===BINO===
But with the exception of that a class of inter-dealer swap relationships, most {{isdama}}s are “bilateral” only really in name: one party — the [[swap dealer]], provides swap products to a client, who consumes them. The client provides the impulse to trade; the client elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The [[dealer]] hedges calculates values, and is burdened with [[regulatory capital]] charges if it doesn’t get its [[close-out netting]] documentation right.


This derives from a working theory that gripped the [[First Men]] as they forged the [[deep magic]] that become the [[First ISDA]]: “a swap contract,” they intoned, “is an equal opportunity sort of an affair; Biblically, righteous in that one is neither a lender nor a borrower under it, but a ''counterparty''”. A counterparty is [[cunisian]] neither one thing nor the other: it is all about possibilities of the relationship. Either fellow may owe or be owed; each has, in theory, the same likelihood as the other of being ''[[in-the-money|in]]'' or ''[[out-of-the-money]]''. This is a bilateral relationship.
This has led to two kinds of bother: firstly a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since dealers set up their templates to assume they are one party and not the other, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can be unseemly. furthermore, when labouring over some neatly iatrogenic [[co-calculation agent]] fallback dispute mechanism upon which your opponent is hotly insisting— you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by the reward in heaven or on earth that you will get for going through the process — it is all to easy to get your [[Party A]]and [[Party B]]back to front, thus burying deep a technical deficiency that no-one will notice until, eighteen years later, when the world is nearing its next [[Apocalypse|apocalyptic meltdown]], the [[Credit officer|chief credit officer]] is running around with her hair on fire, and everyone is glaring at the docs team because the ''key goddamn protection'' has a drafting glitch in it.
 
But with the exception of that a class of inter-dealer swap relationships, most {{isdama}}s are “bilateral” only really in name: one party — the [[swap dealer]], provides swap products to a client, which consumes them. The client provides the impulse to trade; the client elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The dealer hedges calculates values, and is burdened with [[regulatory capital]] charges if it doesn’t get its [[close-out netting]] documentation right.
 
This has led to two kinds of bother: firstly a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since dealers set up their templates to assume they are one party and not the other, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can be unseemly. furthermore, when labouring over some neatly iatrogenic co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism upon which your opponent is hotly insisting— you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by the reward in heaven or on earth that you will get for going through the process — it is all to easy to get your [[Party A]] and [[Party B]] back to front, thus burying deep a technical deficiency that no-one will notice until the world is coming to an end, the chief credit officer is running around with her hair on fire, and everyone is glaring at the docs team because the ''key goddamn protection'' has a drafting glitch in it.

Revision as of 12:35, 31 December 2020

ISDA Anatomy™
Index: Click to expand:Navigation
See ISDA Comparison for a comparison between the 1992 ISDA and the 2002 ISDA.
The Varieties of ISDA Experience
Subject 2002 (wikitext) 1992 (wikitext) 1987 (wikitext)
Preamble Pre Pre Pre
Interpretation 1 1 1
Obligns/Payment 2 2 2
Representations 3 3 3
Agreements 4 4 4
EODs & Term Events 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSTCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityFMTax EventTEUMCEUMATE 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSTCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityTax EventTEUMCEUMATE 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSSCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityTax EventTEUMCEUM
Early Termination 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculations; Payment DatePayments on ETSet-off 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculationsPayments on ETSet-off 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculationsPayments on ET
Transfer 7 7 7
Contractual Currency 8 8 8
Miscellaneous 9 9 9
Offices; Multibranch Parties 10 10 10
Expenses 11 11 11
Notices 12 12 12
Governing Law 13 13 13
Definitions 14 14 14
Schedule Schedule Schedule Schedule
Termination Provisions Part 1 Part 1 Part 1
Tax Representations Part 2 Part 2 Part 2
Documents for Delivery Part 3 Part 3 Part 3
Miscellaneous Part 4 Part 4 Part 4
Other Provisions Part 5 Part 5 Part 5
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

Unlike many financing documents, the ISDA Master Agreement eschews understandable terms for its participants — ones that help you orient who is who: you know, like “Borrower” and “Lender”; “Bank” and “Client”; or “Buyer” and “Seller” — for the decidedly more gnomic “Party A” and “Party B”.

Etymology

This derives from a working theory that gripped the First Men as they forged the deep magic that become the First ISDA: “a swap contract,” they intoned, “is an equal opportunity sort of an affair; Biblically, righteous in that one is neither a lender nor a borrower under it, but a counterparty”. A counterparty is cunisian: neither one thing nor the other, but infused with glorious possibilities. Either fellow may owe or be owed; each has, in theory, the same likelihood as the other of being in or out-of-the-money. This is a bilateral relationship.

BINO

But with the exception of that a class of inter-dealer swap relationships, most ISDA Master Agreements are “bilateral” only really in name: one party — the swap dealer, provides swap products to a client, who consumes them. The client provides the impulse to trade; the client elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The dealer hedges calculates values, and is burdened with regulatory capital charges if it doesn’t get its close-out netting documentation right.

This has led to two kinds of bother: firstly a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since dealers set up their templates to assume they are one party and not the other, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can be unseemly. furthermore, when labouring over some neatly iatrogenic co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism upon which your opponent is hotly insisting— you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by the reward in heaven or on earth that you will get for going through the process — it is all to easy to get your “Party A” and “Party B” back to front, thus burying deep a technical deficiency that no-one will notice until, eighteen years later, when the world is nearing its next apocalyptic meltdown, the chief credit officer is running around with her hair on fire, and everyone is glaring at the docs team because the key goddamn protection has a drafting glitch in it.