|
|
(42 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown) |
Line 1: |
Line 1: |
| ''[[anus matronae parvae malas leges faciunt]]'' - little old ladies - and aggreived welsh hotel owners - make bad law.
| | {{essay|casenote|Greenclose v National Westminster Bank plc|}} |
| | |
| A case opining on the meaning of the apparently harmless {{isdaprov|Notices}} Section (Section {{isdaprov|12}}) of the {{1992ma}}, and in particular what is "an [[electronic messaging system]]" and more to the point what it is ''not'' - which, in the opinion of learned Justice Andrews, includes [[email]].
| |
| | |
| ===Facts===
| |
| | |
| ====The Loan and the interest rate hedge====
| |
| Mr. Leach, of [[Greenclose]], was one of those fabled little old ladies of the law. He was also, the court found, a sophisticated and successful owner of family business running small luxury hotels in and around Wales. But he also seemed to be the wrong end of the [[interest rate swap mis-selling scandal]], wherein NatWest and others lent to mid-sized corporates on condition that they enter a derivative to their hedge interest-rate risk. In Leach's case, Greenclose was obliged to buy a rate collar for five years, and to grant the bank an option to extend it for seven years.
| |
| | |
| The notional point of the hedge was to protect Greenclose against interest rate rises over the term of the loan: interest rates being an uncommonly low 4.5% in 2006, and generally expected, in those good old days, to shortly rise.
| |
| | |
| The bank's theory here is interesting: "I will lend to you at a floating rate for ten years," says the bank. "But if interest rates rise too high, you may not be able to repay your loan. You may default. In that case, ''I'' lose. So therefore I need you to hedge your interest rate risk."
| |
| | |
| At first blush, rising interest rates are the borrower's risk, but - once the borrower has blown up - they become the bank's problem. It was the Bank, not Greenclose, that insisted on the collar. You might think the Bank could otherwise manage that risk by lending at a ''fixed'' interest rate. But it's easy to be wise in hindsight.
| |
| | |
| So NatWest charged Greenclose a premium to reduce its own tail risk to Greenclose's insolvency. With a kicker: Of course, capping future exposure to interest rates that you expect to go up is an expensive business: To reduce the cost, NatWest suggested Greenclose limit its ''downside'' interest rate risk also, and make it a collar - thus limiting Greenclose's exposure to interest rates between 5.07% and 6%. This locked in a rate of at least 5.07% on the loan.
| |
| | |
| Of course, ''low'' interest rates weren't a risk to Greenclose at all. the lower the better.
| |
|
| |
| Greenclose therefore borrowed at that handsome rate but also entered an extendable collar transaction under a 1992 {{isdama}} - the edition is important - which would expire on 30 December 2012 unless NatWest gave proper notice of its extension before that time.
| |
| ====The collar renewal in 2012====
| |
| | |
| If interest rates were agreeably low in 2006, they were even lower in 2012, such that the collar trade was massively out of the money. RBS of course wanted to exercise the option, notwithstanding that there was no real risk to Greenclose, but because they would make a ton of money. Economically this was the saving Greenclose had agreed to forgo by accepting the collar (and the lower cost of the interest rate hedge) in 2006.
| |
| | |
| Now discarding for a moment the fact that the plaintiff was a little old lady, let's be clear here: this is fair enough. NatWest had priced this so it wasn't taking this risk. But it still managed to look like a big, bad bank.
| |
| | |
| =====The errors=====
| |
| Schoolboy error no.1 by NatWest was to agree a notice deadline which expired when Greenclose was highly likelihood to be out of the office. But that's as may be.
| |
| | |
| {{Box|'''Learning Number 1''': Don't set an option expiry period that obliges you to serve notice in the Grundle.}}
| |
| | |
| Error no. 2 - less of a schoolboy one, in this reviewer's opinion, was to assume that an [[email]] - being, after all, an '''electronic''' mail '''message''' sent over a computer '''system''' (so sayeth [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Email Wikipedia]) fell within the meaning of an "[[electronic messaging system]]". Not so, thought Andrews J. because
| |
| {{box|"In 1992, email was not in common use and thus the reference to “[[electronic messaging system]]” is unlikely to have been intended to include it."}}
| |
| | |
| The court does not seem to have heard any evidence on this point. A cursory glance at Wikipedia would suggest this is wildly wrong: the SMTP protocol - over which email is still transferred today - was published in 1982. It is true that the '''expression''' "email" didn't enter the lexicon until 1993 - ''but that is consistent with nascent email being treated as a kind of [[electronic messaging system]]''.
| |
| | |
| Andrews J compared with the equivalent provision in the {{2002ma}}. This '''does'' include [[email]], as a separate item from "[[electronic messaging system]]":
| |
| | |
| {{box|{{ISDA Master Agreement 2002 12}}}}
| |
| | |
| The intellectual endeavour here is interesting: Firstly, to deduce the meaning of the words in that agreement Andrews J looks at ''the intention of the person who crafted the {{1992ma}}'', and not the intentions of the parties who actually negotiated the agreement. The agreement was signed in 2006 - by which stage email was widely known and understood, and it seems fanciful to suggest parties would intend to include all [[electronic messaging systems]] ''but'' [[email]]. There is a long disquisition on what {{ISDA}} intended, which this reviewer submits is utterly irrelevant because ISDA was not a party to the contract.
| |
| | |
| Andrews J needs also to draw a peculiar, narrow meaning of the word "system" to rule that while email may be a means of communicating electronic messages, it is not a "system". [[SWIFT]] is a messaging system. [[SMTP]] over the [[Internet]] is, apparently, not. You have to squint really hard and hold your head in a funny way to follow that logic.
| |
| | |
| What's oddest about this is that the court needed to make ''none'' of these assertions to find NatWest's attempted service wasn't valid, because ''Greenclose hadn't specified an email address in the ISDA {{isdaprov|Schedule}}''. Simply put, ''there was no agreed email address to which NatWest could send Greenclose a message'', however you construe Section {{isdaprov|12}}. Greenclose didn't specify an email address. Case closed.
| |
| | |
| But what would the court have found if [[Greenclose]] ''had'' specified an email address? That he was wrong to do so, because that wasn't an identifier on a valid "[[electronic messaging service]]"?
| |
Greenclose v National Westminster Bank plc [2014] EWHC 1156 (Ch) is a fine example of the JC’s old legal maxim anus matronae parvae malas leges faciunt: Little old ladies (and, in this case, aggrieved Welsh hotel owners) make bad law, Greenclose v National Westminster Bank plc (judgment) opines on the apparently harmless Notices Section (12) of the 1992 ISDA. It considers the meaning of “electronic messaging system” and, saucily, finds that it does not include email.
Let me say that again, in case you missed it: in the eyes of the current common law email does not count as an “electronic messaging system”.
Premium content
Here the free bit runs out. Subscribers click 👉 here. New readers sign up 👉 here and, for ½ a weekly 🍺 go full ninja about all these juicy topics👇
|
See also
References