The curious structure of an MTN: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
Replaced content with "{{essay|repack|MTN structure|{{layman|bond}}}}"
Tag: Replaced
 
(21 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|repack|{{layman|bond}}}}You will know old Grandpa Contrarian’s story of [[the farmer and the sheep]]. It is illustrated richly in every cove, inlet and waterway of the financial markets, but is no better exemplified than in the genetic structure of a [[medium term note]] programme.
{{essay|repack|MTN structure|{{layman|bond}}}}
 
These, for the fortunately uninitiated, are architectural structures by which corporations raise funds in the international [[debt capital market]]s. Their history is long and mildly diverting at best — the type who naturally deals in debt instruments is not really given to intrigue — but for our purposes it is important.
 
=== Conceptual underpinnings ===
Now: as per the panel summary, a [[bond]] of any kind is an [[IOU]], in that it represents an entitlement to be repaid a loan. In earlier epochs one would borrow against a “note” — literally, a signed piece of paper indicating your preparedness to pay a sum to whoever presented it, in exchange for its surrender.
 
The neat thing about this kind of note is its transferability: the original lender can “[[negotiability|negotiate]]” it — sell it<ref>Or pledge, or lend it.</ref> without the issuer’s permission, or even knowledge — and its value will be the [[present value]] of the issuer’s promise to pay. A note is a unilateral contract, therefore. A conventional loan is a ''bilateral'' contract, and the job of transferring ones rights and liabilities under it is more involved, and often requires the cooperation of the borrower.
 
The other neat thing about notes compared to loans is that you can easily divide a big borrowing into lots of little notes, rather than a single big one. Thus, you can access a wider pool of lenders — including [[Belgian dentist]]<nowiki/>s, as we will see — each of whom can manage its own exposure without reference to the others, by buying or selling bonds in the secondary market.
 
Notes therefore are more liquid, transferable things, and while they are outstanding the issuer need not even know who its creditors are: they hove into view only upon payment of [[principal]] or [[interest]], when they would show up at the issuer’s office with their instrument in hand.
 
=== Industrialisation of debt securities ===
This all being the case, notes quickly became popular, and the process of issuing, selling and maintaining them industrialised. Notes were “security printed”, like banknotes. [[Interest]] payments were represented by perforated [[Coupon|coupons]] that could be detached and presented (or “stripped” and separately traded): for a long-dated bond, where there wasn’t room for all the coupons, there would be “[[talon]]s” attached entitling the bearer to a fresh strip of coupons. Issuers appointed banks as “[[paying agent]]s” to handle the mechanics of dealing with holders, paying out on presentation and so on. In some jurisdictions<ref>America being a prime example, thanks to the glorious strictures of the [[Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act]] ([[TEFRA]]) of 1982, which introduced punitive tax treatment for bearer bonds, on the grounds that they were inherently fishy, income-sheltering things — a quality that never bothered the Belgian dental profession in the same way.</ref> issuers needed to maintain a record of noteholders, so created “registered” notes which were profoundly different in legal ''concept'' — title transferred by entry in the register, whereas with a [[bearer instrument]] the security itself ''was'' the debt and title passed by delivery — and there needed to be terms to deal with certain unwanted contingencies: replacing lost or mutilated notes; provisions for noteholder meetings to consider amendments to terms and so on.
 
Now an [[IOU]] is a simple enough thing: the legal architecture making it all possible was another thing altogether: [[trust deed]]<nowiki/>s, paying agency agreements, [[dealer]] agreements, [[prospectus]]<nowiki/>es and so on, and the up-front cost of a “stand-alone” debt issuance was formidable. Thus emerged the [[medium term note programme]] — a pre-crafted architecture containing all the standard terms, appointments and so on, which an issuer could quickly “tap” when it needed to, in a fraction of the time and cost.
 
In parallel the information revolution arrived and notes started to trade electronically, in a [[clearing system]]<ref>In the European markets, there are two major [[clearing system]]s: [[Euroclear]] and [[Clearstream]].</ref>. Here noteholders’ interests were represented as electronic entries in their clearing system accounts there was no need for security printing, perforated coupons, a wide network of paying agents, and the identity for the time being of the holders was ascertainable, at least by the clearing system, which had to maintain the records on order to ensure everyone got paid. At the very heart there was still a physically printed note: just one: a “global note”, representing all the nominally issued notes, held by a “[[common depositary]]” — a custodian for the electronic clearing systems in which the notes are traded.
 
=== Residual DNA ===
By the 1990s, all notes, bonds and other securities were electronically cleared, and none has been security printed since. Nonetheless, the MTN terms and structure still bear traces of their physical biology, a bit like tailbones, appendixes and male nipples. The basic rationale is “well, the [[clearing system]]s might not work one day — you know, there could be some kind of post-apocalyptic, Mad Max-style future with everyone driving round in battle trucks and drinking their own urine — so I might need to change these into security-printed definitive notes, so we better leave these terms in just in case”.
 
Now the [[JC]] would be the last one to pooh-pooh the idea of a dystopian future — given the last few years he rather expects it at some stage, in fact — but, really: if you are eating caterpillars, presenting your coupons to the Luxembourg paying agent is going to be a long way down your list of priorities.
 
In any case, this useless DNA makes for a great deal more complicatedness than, in practice one really needs. Your bond terms and conditions have to deal with the following:
 
* [[Registered security|Registered]] or [[Bearer security|bearer]] form
* [[Clearing system|Electronically cleared]] or [[Definitive security|definitive]]
* Where definitive and bearer, mechanics of presenting coupons, talons and so on.
 
===The logical structure of legal documents===
This leads us on to [[Semantic code project|one of our pet interests]]: why are legal documents so convoluted, and what can one do to correct it. For this we need to delve into the underlying logical structure of a contract.
 
Any legal statement, however [[Fish Principle|Fish]]ily articulated, boils down to a basic logical proposition, rather like software code, with propositions, conditions, logic gates, if/then statements, and so on, only we call them definitions, obligations, rights, discretions, options and so on.
 
Any logic gate — in legal language, an alternative, choice or option, increases the inherent complicatedness of a proposition.
 
Take this statement about cricket and rugby balls:
 
{{subtable|
A ball: <br>
(a) if it is red
:(i) if it is round
::(A) may not be used for rugby
::(B) may be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
:(ii) if it is oval:
::(A) may be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
(b) if it is white:
:(i) if it is round:
::(A) may not be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may be used for one-day cricket
:(ii) if it is oval:
::(A) may be used for rugby
::(B) may not be used for test cricket
::(C) may not be used for one-day cricket
}}
 
Or you could render it thus:
 
{{subtable|
A ball: <br>
(a) if it is oval
:(i) may be used for rugby
:(ii) may not be used for cricket
(b) if it is round:
:(i) may not be used for rugby
::(a) if it is red:
:::(I) may be used for test cricket
:::(II) may not be used for one-day cricket
::(a) if it is white:
:::(I) may not be used for test cricket
:::(II) may be used for one-day cricket
}}
 
There are more and less efficient ways of organising a logical structure containing those propositions.
 
 
{{sa}}
 
* [[Medium term note programme]]
* [[Repackaging programme]]
{{Ref}}

Latest revision as of 14:07, 3 October 2023

The Law and Lore of Repackaging

“bond” as explained to my neighbor Phil

A bond (also called a “note”, “MTN” or a “debt security”) is a form of loan. It is like an IOU from a company or a government. Instead of taking one big loan from a bank, a company issues lots of little loans, in the form of bonds to investors. To buy a bond is to lend money to the issuing company, who must repay that money by “redeeming” the bond its stated maturity date. In the good old days, bonds were security-printed certificates with the loan terms and conditions printed on them.

Repayment to bearer: The company will pay principal and interest to the “bearer” of a bond — that is, whoever holds it, and who turns up on the correct payment date and presents the bond to the issuer for redemption.

Interest coupons: If interest is payable, the bond will have coupons — literally, little perforated tabs that you can tear off and present separately — for each interest payment. Hence the expression “coupon” has become synonymous in modern finance with interest.

Transferability: Because the issuer pays whoever holds the bond, this means the bond is negotiable — any bondholder can sell its bond to another investor without the issuer’s permission or knowledge. The issuer doesn't care: it has to redeem the same number of bonds, whoever holds them.

Electronic trading: Nowadays, almost all bonds trade and settle electronically, inside clearing systems, so there are no certificates or coupons, and everything happens in the blink of an eye. But the principle is the same.

Financial concepts my neighbour Phil was asking about when I borrowed his mower.

Index: Click to expand:

Edit

Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

You will know by now old Grandpa Contrarian’s story of the farmer and the sheep. It is illustrated richly in every cove, inlet and waterway of the financial markets, but is no better exemplified than in the genetic structure of a medium term note programme.

These, for the fortunately uninitiated, are architectural structures by which corporations raise funds in the international debt capital markets. Their history is long and mildly diverting at best — the type who naturally deals in debt instruments is not really given to intrigue — but for our purposes it is important.

Conceptual underpinnings

Now: as per the panel summary, a bond of any kind is an IOU, in that it represents an entitlement to be repaid a loan. In earlier epochs one would borrow against a “note” — literally, a signed piece of paper indicating your preparedness to pay a sum to whoever presented it, in exchange for its surrender.

The neat thing about this kind of note is its transferability: the original lender can “negotiate” it — sell it[1] without the issuer’s permission, or even knowledge — and its value will be the present value of the issuer’s promise to pay. A note is a unilateral contract, therefore. A conventional loan is a bilateral contract, and the job of transferring ones rights and liabilities under it is more involved, and often requires the cooperation of the borrower.

The other neat thing about notes compared to loans is that you can easily divide a big borrowing into lots of little notes, rather than a single big one. Thus, you can access a wider pool of lenders — including Belgian dentists, as we will see — each of whom can manage its own exposure without reference to the others, by buying or selling bonds in the secondary market.

Notes therefore are more liquid, transferable things, and while they are outstanding the issuer need not even know who its creditors are: they hove into view only upon payment of principal or interest, when they would show up at the issuer’s office with their instrument in hand.

Industrialisation of debt securities

This all being the case, notes quickly became popular, and the process of issuing, selling and maintaining them industrialised. Notes were “security printed”, like banknotes. Interest payments were represented by perforated coupons that could be detached and presented (or “stripped” and separately traded): for a long-dated bond, where there wasn’t room for all the coupons, there would be “talons” attached entitling the bearer to a fresh strip of coupons. Issuers appointed banks as “paying agents” to handle the mechanics of dealing with holders, paying out on presentation and so on. In some jurisdictions[2] issuers needed to maintain a record of noteholders, so created “registered” notes which were profoundly different in legal concept — title transferred by entry in the register, whereas with a bearer instrument the security itself was the debt and title passed by delivery — and there needed to be terms to deal with certain unwanted contingencies: replacing lost or mutilated notes; provisions for noteholder meetings to consider amendments to terms and so on.

Now an IOU is a simple enough thing: the legal architecture making it all possible was another thing altogether: trust deeds, paying agency agreements, dealer agreements, prospectuses and so on, and the up-front cost of a “stand-alone” debt issuance was formidable. Thus emerged the medium term note programme — a pre-crafted architecture containing all the standard terms, appointments and so on, which an issuer could quickly “tap” when it needed to, in a fraction of the time and cost.

In parallel the information revolution arrived and notes started to trade electronically, in a clearing system[3]. Here noteholders’ interests were represented as electronic entries in their clearing system accounts there was no need for security printing, perforated coupons, a wide network of paying agents, and the identity for the time being of the holders was ascertainable, at least by the clearing system, which had to maintain the records on order to ensure everyone got paid. At the very heart there was still a physically printed note: just one: a “global note”, representing all the nominally issued notes, held by a “common depositary” — a custodian for the electronic clearing systems in which the notes are traded.

Residual DNA

By the 1990s, all notes, bonds and other securities were electronically cleared, and none has been security printed since. Nonetheless, the MTN terms and structure still bear traces of their physical biology, a bit like tailbones, appendixes and male nipples. The basic rationale is “well, the clearing systems might not work one day — you know, there could be some kind of post-apocalyptic, Mad Max-style future with everyone driving round in battle trucks and drinking their own urine — so I might need to change these into security-printed definitive notes, so we better leave these terms in just in case”.

Now the JC would be the last one to pooh-pooh the idea of a dystopian future — given the last few years he rather expects it at some stage, in fact — but, really: if you are eating caterpillars, presenting your coupons to the Luxembourg paying agent is going to be a long way down your list of priorities.

For reasons we can only put down to entropy, international bond terms and conditions are all shot through with laborious mechanical conditions that deal with how payments are made, where, by whom, on what conditions, to whom, should the notes be held outside a clearing system — a circumstance which, in the year of our Lord 2022, categorically will not happen — but which, thanks to the vagaries of historical appetite, meant might happen in a number of ways.

Premium content
Here the free bit runs out. Subscribers click 👉 here. New readers sign up 👉 here and, for ½ a weekly 🍺 go full ninja about all these juicy topics👇

See also

References

  1. Or pledge, or lend it.
  2. America being a prime example, thanks to the glorious strictures of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act (TEFRA) of 1982, which introduced punitive tax treatment for bearer bonds, on the grounds that they were inherently fishy, income-sheltering things — a quality that never bothered the Belgian dental profession in the same way.
  3. In the European markets, there are two major clearing systems: Euroclear and Clearstream.