Template:Erisa netting: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
===={{tag|ERISA netting}}====
===={{tag|ERISA netting}}====
Famously, ERISA plans tend to be set '''not''' to [[Netting|net]], and for the unholiest of reasons, courtesy of the opinions committee of a leading [[U.S. law firm]] which prudence counsels it would be wiser not to name<ref>Definitely not Cadwalader, obviously.</ref>, but upon whom the whole market relies.
Famously, ERISA plans tend to be set '''not''' to [[Netting|net]], and for the unholiest of reasons, courtesy of the opinions committee of a leading [[U.S. law firm]] which prudence counsels it would be wiser not to name, but upon whom the whole market relies.


This firm cannot bring itself to rule out the risk that, when resolving an insolvent [[ERISA plan]], a court would interpret {{tag|ERISA}} as incorporating the US [[Bankruptcy Code]] ''as it stood in 1971'' to the insolvency of the plan, rather than the Code ''as it stands at the time of insolvency''. That’s a problem, because the “[[safe harbor]]s” one relies upon for safely [[Close out|closing out]] swaps were only put into the [[Bankruptcy Code]] in the 1980s.<ref>Being WHEN SWAPS WERE INVENTED. See [[swap history]].</ref> So, no netting against [[ERISA plan]]s. Just in case.
This firm cannot bring itself to rule out the risk that, when resolving an insolvent [[ERISA plan]], a court would interpret {{tag|ERISA}} as incorporating the US [[Bankruptcy Code]] ''as it stood in 1971'' to the insolvency of the plan, rather than the Code ''as it stands at the time of insolvency''. That’s a problem, because the “[[safe harbor]]s” one relies upon for safely [[Close out|closing out]] swaps were only put into the [[Bankruptcy Code]] in the 1980s.<ref>Being WHEN SWAPS WERE INVENTED. See [[swap history]].</ref> So, no netting against [[ERISA plan]]s. Just in case.
Line 12: Line 12:
Seriously. That’s it.
Seriously. That’s it.


It is a frankly fantastical fear: Not only is it hard to know, at this remove, what the US [[Bankruptcy Code]] ''said'' in 1971, much less how it might have been interpreted in those days, but many of the institutions and concepts it relies on may since have been abolished or materially changed. Who knows? perhaps some old hippyish [[safe harbor]]s from the 1960s that might apply to swaps. But then again, it’s not that likely — and it is just as harsh to blame US legislators for not enacting [[Safe harbor|safe harbors]] for swaps before the 1980s — since ''there [[Swap history|''weren’t'' any swaps before 1981]]''.
It is a frankly fantastical fear: Not only is it hard to know, at this remove, what the US [[Bankruptcy Code]] ''said'' in 1971, much less how it might have been interpreted in those days, but many of the institutions and concepts it relies on may since have been abolished or materially changed. Who knows? perhaps some old [[safe harbor]]s from the 1960s might apply to swaps. But then again, since ''there [[Swap history|''weren’t'' any swaps before 1981]],'' it’s not exactly likely. It would be an imaginative legislator indeed who catered in 1971 for something no-one had even had the presence of mind to think up for another decade.
 
===== Originalism? =====
There is a school of thought in US constitutional law — “originalism” — that when construing a legal text one should extract the original understanding at its time of adoption, disregarding all subsequent changes in law, moral consensus or technology. This is popular with conservatives, the four Yorkshiremen, people who think they don’t make things like they used to, but who are in denial about how crappy things used to be, and indeed how impossible it is to know, over the years, what those who framed a text had in mind in the first place anyway. It is a, ostensibly, a device from ''preventing'' judicial activism in favour of express legislative and constitutional amendment, but is in its own way just as wilful an exercise in juicial imagination. Perhaps we should call it judicial passivism, or even judicial passive-''aggressivism''. It is also to assume that legislation — especially consitutional legislation — is easily amended. But the U.S. constitution has long since transcended mere legislation and as become some kind of sacred article of faith for the American people.  ''No-one'' is amending that. All that is left is creative interpretation of what it means to suit the current social climate.

Revision as of 10:30, 12 March 2024

====ERISA netting==== Famously, ERISA plans tend to be set not to net, and for the unholiest of reasons, courtesy of the opinions committee of a leading U.S. law firm which prudence counsels it would be wiser not to name, but upon whom the whole market relies.

This firm cannot bring itself to rule out the risk that, when resolving an insolvent ERISA plan, a court would interpret ERISA as incorporating the US Bankruptcy Code as it stood in 1971 to the insolvency of the plan, rather than the Code as it stands at the time of insolvency. That’s a problem, because the “safe harbors” one relies upon for safely closing out swaps were only put into the Bankruptcy Code in the 1980s.[1] So, no netting against ERISA plans. Just in case.

Let me break that down:

Seriously. That’s it.

It is a frankly fantastical fear: Not only is it hard to know, at this remove, what the US Bankruptcy Code said in 1971, much less how it might have been interpreted in those days, but many of the institutions and concepts it relies on may since have been abolished or materially changed. Who knows? perhaps some old safe harbors from the 1960s might apply to swaps. But then again, since there weren’t any swaps before 1981, it’s not exactly likely. It would be an imaginative legislator indeed who catered in 1971 for something no-one had even had the presence of mind to think up for another decade.

Originalism?

There is a school of thought in US constitutional law — “originalism” — that when construing a legal text one should extract the original understanding at its time of adoption, disregarding all subsequent changes in law, moral consensus or technology. This is popular with conservatives, the four Yorkshiremen, people who think they don’t make things like they used to, but who are in denial about how crappy things used to be, and indeed how impossible it is to know, over the years, what those who framed a text had in mind in the first place anyway. It is a, ostensibly, a device from preventing judicial activism in favour of express legislative and constitutional amendment, but is in its own way just as wilful an exercise in juicial imagination. Perhaps we should call it judicial passivism, or even judicial passive-aggressivism. It is also to assume that legislation — especially consitutional legislation — is easily amended. But the U.S. constitution has long since transcended mere legislation and as become some kind of sacred article of faith for the American people. No-one is amending that. All that is left is creative interpretation of what it means to suit the current social climate.

  1. Being WHEN SWAPS WERE INVENTED. See swap history.