Template:Financialisation of the markets: Difference between revisions
Amwelladmin (talk | contribs) Created page with "Bear in mind the broad sweep of three historical trends that converged in the 1980s. =====Financialisation===== First, the rapid onset of ''financialisation'' of, well, ''everything'', due to parallel developments in information technology. Through the Seventies and Eighties, Western markets acquired the mental habits and technical systems needed to look at financial risk in a much more detailed, segmentable, way, as substrate-neutral ''derivatives'' of real..." |
Amwelladmin (talk | contribs) No edit summary |
||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
Bear in mind the broad sweep of three historical trends that converged in the 1980s. | Bear in mind the broad sweep of three historical trends that converged in the 1980s. | ||
=====Financialisation===== | =====Financialisation===== | ||
First, the rapid onset of ''[[financialisation]]'' of, well, ''everything'', due to parallel developments in [[information technology]]. Through the Seventies and Eighties, Western markets acquired the mental habits and technical systems needed to look at financial risk in a much more detailed, segmentable | First, the rapid onset of ''[[financialisation]]'' of, well, ''everything'', due to parallel developments in [[information technology]]. Through the Seventies and Eighties, Western markets acquired the mental habits and technical systems they needed to look at financial risk in a much more detailed, segmentable way: as “[[substrate-neutral]]” ''derivatives'' of real-world propositions. | ||
At the same time, the market developed the legal and contractual tools to implement this new way of thinking about risks. Principle among them was a new class of [[Master trading agreement|bilateral financial contracts]] unlike anything | Financial instruments traded electronically. Increasingly, institutions modelled their risk with computers. They unbundled big, organic, ineffable risks into discrete tradable components: first, [[market risk]] and [[credit risk]]. Then into more esoteric measures: [[volatility]]. [[Liquidity]]. [[Convexity]]. [[Correlation]]. [[Credit value adjustment|Credit]] and [[Debt value adjustment|debt]] value. | ||
At the same time, the market developed the legal and contractual tools to implement this new way of thinking about risks. Principle among them was a new class of [[Master trading agreement|bilateral financial contracts]] unlike anything the world had seen before, in which the usual master-slave relationship between creditors and debtors and between bankers and their customers were rendered — ''apparently'' — moot. There was no lender or borrower. The parties were equals: ''traders''. | |||
The {{isdama}} was at the vanguard of these new bilateral contracts.<ref>Though see [[a swap as a loan]] for a contrarian argument on that.</ref> | The {{isdama}} was at the vanguard of these new bilateral contracts.<ref>Though see [[a swap as a loan]] for a contrarian argument on that.</ref> | ||
At the same time, powered by the same irrepressible forces of modernity, the market internationalised. Reducing financial instruments to electronic impulses made cross-border trade easier. While central banks could manage prudential supervision in their own jurisdictions, it was | At the same time, powered by the same irrepressible forces of modernity, the market internationalised. Reducing financial instruments to electronic impulses made cross-border trade easier. While central banks could manage prudential supervision in their own jurisdictions, it was difficult for them to do it across global financial markets where different regulatory regimes presented all kinds of arbitrage opportunities. | ||
=====New capital regulation===== | =====New capital regulation===== | ||
These developments in banking and market technology called for a more sophisticated framework for managing institutional risk in the global markets. Banks were increasingly interconnected, both across exchanges and in private [[over-the-counter]] markets, and the speed at which they traded | These developments in banking and market technology called for a more sophisticated framework for managing institutional risk in the global markets. Banks were increasingly interconnected, both across exchanges and in private [[over-the-counter]] markets, and the speed at which they traded, and at which trading values fluctuated, meant there was heightened systemic risk should major institutions get into trouble. The Latin American debt crisis was a case in point. Even smaller participants could have a disproportionate effect on system stability. We saw this, a bit later, when the brainbox-stuffed pioneering relative value arbitrage hedge fund [[Long Term Capital Management]] blew up and almost took Western banking civilisation with it. Some would say that would have been no bad thing. | ||
At the same time the innovative financial instruments, which tended to be [[leverage]]d and shared few of the characteristics of traditional financial instruments, meant effective capital ratios at financial institutions declined over the 1980s. It became apparent that the worst-case loss scenario for a [[master trading agreement]] like the ISDA was orders of magnitude greater than that presented by exposure to, for example, a syndicated loan. As a result, the [[Basel Committee on Banking Supervision]] introduced harmonised global standards for the capital treatment of financial instruments including | At the same time the innovative financial instruments, which tended to be [[leverage]]d and shared few of the characteristics of traditional financial instruments, meant effective capital ratios at financial institutions declined over the 1980s. It became apparent that the worst-case loss scenario for a [[master trading agreement]] like the ISDA was orders of magnitude greater than that presented by exposure to, for example, a syndicated loan. As a result, the [[Basel Committee on Banking Supervision]] introduced harmonised global standards for the capital treatment of financial instruments, including these new swap contracts. These rules, now known as ''[[Basel I]]'', were first published in 1986. The following year, the {{1987ma}} arrived. | ||
=====Corporate resolution didn’t change===== | =====Corporate resolution didn’t change===== | ||
Line 18: | Line 20: | ||
Swaps remained an arcane part of the international capital markets. They were not relevant to the SMEs. Companies regulators, assignees and administrators did not well understand them, or how they worked. Having local tax and employment liabilities and “trade credit” arrangements in mind, Bankruptcy regimes tended to confer broad discretions on receivers and liquidators to ensure fair outcomes for all claimants upon a company’s resolution. | Swaps remained an arcane part of the international capital markets. They were not relevant to the SMEs. Companies regulators, assignees and administrators did not well understand them, or how they worked. Having local tax and employment liabilities and “trade credit” arrangements in mind, Bankruptcy regimes tended to confer broad discretions on receivers and liquidators to ensure fair outcomes for all claimants upon a company’s resolution. | ||
But broad discretion means ''lack of certainty''. Especially for highly unusual arrangements like | But broad discretion means ''lack of certainty'', and financial markets do not ''like'' [[Uncertain|uncertainty]]. Especially not for highly unusual, levered arrangements like swaps, which are not by nature creditor-debtor arrangements. Should an administrator try to “[[cherry-pick]]” the [[in-the-money]] transactions in a swap portfolio, the implications for [[swap dealer]]s — who had only entered into them at all on the assumption that all exposures, positive and negative, would net down to a single number — could be far worse, and far more ''volatile'', than the corresponding risks presented by an ordinary loan or trade invoice. | ||
[[Basel I]] addressed this “local insolvency risk” | [[Basel I]] addressed this “local insolvency risk” by requiring swap dealers to obtain written and reasoned legal opinions that, under local bankruptcy rules, their master agreements could not be [[cherry-pick|cherry-picked]] in this way. that the “[[single agreement]]” concept would work, and their rights to apply [[close-out netting]] would be respected. | ||
And this is where the [[Bankruptcy as a phase transition|phase transition into bankruptcy]] becomes important. Typically, while a company is still solvent and | And this is where the [[Bankruptcy as a phase transition|phase transition into bankruptcy]] becomes important. Typically, while a company is still solvent and trading in the ordinary course, its [[master trading agreement|master trading agreements]] may be enforced, and netted, according to their terms. It is only at the point of formal [[bankruptcy]] that the phantom [[bankruptcy shenanigans|shenanigans]] of wide-ranging equitable discretion hove into view. In some jurisdictions, the point at which everything changes is a split second, and getting the right side of it makes all the difference. |
Latest revision as of 11:29, 12 October 2024
Bear in mind the broad sweep of three historical trends that converged in the 1980s.
Financialisation
First, the rapid onset of financialisation of, well, everything, due to parallel developments in information technology. Through the Seventies and Eighties, Western markets acquired the mental habits and technical systems they needed to look at financial risk in a much more detailed, segmentable way: as “substrate-neutral” derivatives of real-world propositions.
Financial instruments traded electronically. Increasingly, institutions modelled their risk with computers. They unbundled big, organic, ineffable risks into discrete tradable components: first, market risk and credit risk. Then into more esoteric measures: volatility. Liquidity. Convexity. Correlation. Credit and debt value.
At the same time, the market developed the legal and contractual tools to implement this new way of thinking about risks. Principle among them was a new class of bilateral financial contracts unlike anything the world had seen before, in which the usual master-slave relationship between creditors and debtors and between bankers and their customers were rendered — apparently — moot. There was no lender or borrower. The parties were equals: traders.
The ISDA Master Agreement was at the vanguard of these new bilateral contracts.[1]
At the same time, powered by the same irrepressible forces of modernity, the market internationalised. Reducing financial instruments to electronic impulses made cross-border trade easier. While central banks could manage prudential supervision in their own jurisdictions, it was difficult for them to do it across global financial markets where different regulatory regimes presented all kinds of arbitrage opportunities.
New capital regulation
These developments in banking and market technology called for a more sophisticated framework for managing institutional risk in the global markets. Banks were increasingly interconnected, both across exchanges and in private over-the-counter markets, and the speed at which they traded, and at which trading values fluctuated, meant there was heightened systemic risk should major institutions get into trouble. The Latin American debt crisis was a case in point. Even smaller participants could have a disproportionate effect on system stability. We saw this, a bit later, when the brainbox-stuffed pioneering relative value arbitrage hedge fund Long Term Capital Management blew up and almost took Western banking civilisation with it. Some would say that would have been no bad thing.
At the same time the innovative financial instruments, which tended to be leveraged and shared few of the characteristics of traditional financial instruments, meant effective capital ratios at financial institutions declined over the 1980s. It became apparent that the worst-case loss scenario for a master trading agreement like the ISDA was orders of magnitude greater than that presented by exposure to, for example, a syndicated loan. As a result, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision introduced harmonised global standards for the capital treatment of financial instruments, including these new swap contracts. These rules, now known as Basel I, were first published in 1986. The following year, the 1987 ISDA arrived.
Corporate resolution didn’t change
While there was a good deal of harmony in the international capital markets, many domestic bankruptcy regimes — which were targeted at small and medium-sized enterprises and typically did not have such an international focus — did not similarly change or update.
Swaps remained an arcane part of the international capital markets. They were not relevant to the SMEs. Companies regulators, assignees and administrators did not well understand them, or how they worked. Having local tax and employment liabilities and “trade credit” arrangements in mind, Bankruptcy regimes tended to confer broad discretions on receivers and liquidators to ensure fair outcomes for all claimants upon a company’s resolution.
But broad discretion means lack of certainty, and financial markets do not like uncertainty. Especially not for highly unusual, levered arrangements like swaps, which are not by nature creditor-debtor arrangements. Should an administrator try to “cherry-pick” the in-the-money transactions in a swap portfolio, the implications for swap dealers — who had only entered into them at all on the assumption that all exposures, positive and negative, would net down to a single number — could be far worse, and far more volatile, than the corresponding risks presented by an ordinary loan or trade invoice.
Basel I addressed this “local insolvency risk” by requiring swap dealers to obtain written and reasoned legal opinions that, under local bankruptcy rules, their master agreements could not be cherry-picked in this way. that the “single agreement” concept would work, and their rights to apply close-out netting would be respected.
And this is where the phase transition into bankruptcy becomes important. Typically, while a company is still solvent and trading in the ordinary course, its master trading agreements may be enforced, and netted, according to their terms. It is only at the point of formal bankruptcy that the phantom shenanigans of wide-ranging equitable discretion hove into view. In some jurisdictions, the point at which everything changes is a split second, and getting the right side of it makes all the difference.
- ↑ Though see a swap as a loan for a contrarian argument on that.