Template:M intro isda on termination: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Line 1: Line 1:
{{drop|C|ommerce gives the}} lie to the idea that life is a [[zero-sum game]]. This was [[Adam Smith]]’s great insight: things need not be [[Thomas Hobbes|nasty, brutish and short]] and, when it comes to commerce, generally aren’t.  
{{drop|C|ommerce gives the}} lie to the idea that life is a [[zero-sum game]]. This was [[Adam Smith]]’s great insight: things need not be [[Thomas Hobbes|nasty, brutish and short]] and, when it comes to commerce, generally aren’t.  


Each of us will only strike a bargain if we think, on our own terms, we’ll be better off as a result. That being so, once we’ve built a good business relationship, there is no good reason to ''end'' it. All being well, trade is an [[infinite game]]. If we are good enough at it, we can keep its [[feedback loop|positive feedback loop]] going, for the mutual betterment of everyone, indefinitely. ''Infinitely'', even.  
Each of us will only strike a bargain if we think, on our own terms, we’ll be better off as a result. That being so, once we’ve built a good business relationship, there is no good reason to ''end'' it. All being well, trade is an [[infinite game]]. If we are good enough at it, we can keep its [[Feedback loop|positive feedback loop]] going, for the mutual betterment of everyone, indefinitely. ''Infinitely'', even.  


Therefore, we wish our relationships well and pray Godspeed for their long and fruity lives. Should the plums dangling from this or that branch shrivel; if things become more trouble than they’re worth, we can of course call time and bid our relationship a peaceful transition to the hereafter.  
Therefore, we wish our relationships well and pray Godspeed for their long and fruity lives. Should the plums dangling from this or that branch shrivel; if things become more trouble than they’re worth, we can of course call time and bid our relationship a peaceful transition to the hereafter.  


But still, things do not always work out quite so equably. Sometimes, an ill wind blows. Relationships become fraught, counterparties get themselves in a pickle.
But still, things do not always work out quite so equably. Sometimes, an ill wind blows. Relationships become fraught, counterparties get themselves in a pickle.


Therefore, we pack our trunk with tools, implements and weapons with which, if we must, we can engineer a faster exit from our contracts.  
Therefore, we pack our trunk with tools, implements and weapons with which, if we must, we can engineer a faster exit from our contracts.  
Line 16: Line 16:
{{drop|N|ow the great}} majority of [[financial contract]]s are between a “''provider''” on one side — a [[bank]], [[broker]] or [[dealer]] providing a “''service''”, broadly described: money outright, finance against an asset or a financial exposure — and a “''[[customer]]''” on the other who ''pays'' for that service. The customer is, as ever, king: the service exists for her exclusive benefit: the provider’s only wish is to manage its resources to most efficiently provide that service and extract a [[fee]], [[commission]] or economic [[rent]] by way of [[consideration]] for it.  
{{drop|N|ow the great}} majority of [[financial contract]]s are between a “''provider''” on one side — a [[bank]], [[broker]] or [[dealer]] providing a “''service''”, broadly described: money outright, finance against an asset or a financial exposure — and a “''[[customer]]''” on the other who ''pays'' for that service. The customer is, as ever, king: the service exists for her exclusive benefit: the provider’s only wish is to manage its resources to most efficiently provide that service and extract a [[fee]], [[commission]] or economic [[rent]] by way of [[consideration]] for it.  


“Providers” are indifferent to how the instruments they serve perform. They do not mean to be “the other side” of the trade. They are, loosely, ''[[intermediaries]]''. [[Agent|Agents]]. They match risk-takers, collect a fee and wish the parties well without taking sides: they are “[[compassion]]ate”, not “[[empathy|empathetic]]”. As long as their customers remain in fine fettle, they should never need, much less want, to ''terminate'' their services, for that is how they earn a crust.  
“Providers” are indifferent to how the instruments they serve perform. They do not mean to be “the other side” of the trade. They are, loosely, ''[[intermediaries]]''. [[Agent|Agents]]. They match risk-takers, collect a fee and wish the parties well without taking sides: they are “[[compassion]]ate”, not “[[Empathy|empathetic]]”. As long as their customers remain in fine fettle, they should never need, much less want, to ''terminate'' their services, for that is how they earn a crust.  


But all the same we should note something important here: the expectations of parties to a service contract are very different: the customer takes risk and retains the prerogative to go ''off'' risk as she sees fit, as long as she pays the provider’s fees and whatever it needs to terminate the arrangements it made to provide the service in the first place: its “[[breakage costs]]”.
But all the same we should note something important here: the expectations of parties to a service contract are very different: the customer takes risk and retains the prerogative to go ''off'' risk as she sees fit, as long as she pays the provider’s fees and whatever it needs to terminate the arrangements it made to provide the service in the first place: its “[[breakage costs]]”.
Line 29: Line 29:


====Without cause====
====Without cause====
{{drop|T|erminations “without cause”}}<ref>You hear these described as “no-fault” terminations, but there is no ''fault'' in a termination brought about by unforeseen externalities, either.</ref> arise ''just because'' — no fault, no pressing need; just a gradual drifting apart of interests. As we grow in life, the things we value change. Passions of youth dampen, we tend more towards scabrous songs of experience than exuberant songs of innocence. Here we prescribe a notice period long enough to allow a customer to make alternative arrangements, but otherwise, we wish each other well and carry on our way. These will generally be “clean-up” rights. They will exist under framework contracts and will not impair in-flight services. A service provider must honour any specific Transaction terms already on the books before being allowed to move on. Without cause termination is there to clear out low-value and dormant clientry from the administrative record: there may be ongoing compliance or operational costs of maintaining inactive clients on the books.
{{drop|T|erminations “without cause”}}<ref>You hear these described as “no-fault” terminations, but there is no ''fault'' in a termination brought about by unforeseen externalities, either.</ref> arise ''just because'' — no fault, no pressing need; just a gradual drifting apart of interests. As we grow in life, the things we value change. Passions of youth dampen, we tend more towards scabrous songs of experience than exuberant songs of innocence. If this should mean our commercial paths diverge, we prescribe a notice period long enough to allow each other to make reasonable alternative arrangements, but otherwise, we wish each other well and carry on our way.  
 
“Without cause” termination rights for a service provider will generally be “clean-up” arrangements: to clear out low-value and dormant clientry whose mere presence on the books implies ongoing compliance or operational costs. These rights will not usually impair in-flight Transactions, which a service provider must still see through before it can be allowed to move on.  


=====Pseudo-termination rights=====
=====Pseudo-termination rights=====
[[Dealer]]s sometimes do retain rights to terminate customer Transactions without cause, but these will typically be ''pseudo''-termination rights that the dealer never means to use. Sometimes a regulated institution must have the power to terminate transactions for capital reasons, even though it never expects to use them in real life. Curiously, these are motivated by their own costs of doing business and not the customer’s solvency.<ref>See {{isdaprov|Automatic Early Termination}}, which is an extreme example of a pseudo termination right: in that it triggers automatically. Much more to say about that on the {{isdaprov|AET}} page.</ref>
[[Dealer]]s sometimes must have rights to terminate in-flight customer Transactions on notice without reason. These will often be ''pseudo”'' rights that a dealer must ''have'' but will never actually ''use''. These rights help to optimise their liquidity and capital buffers, therefore reducing the dealers’ own costs of doing customer business.<ref>See {{isdaprov|Automatic Early Termination}}, which is an extreme example of a pseudo termination right: in that it triggers automatically. Much more to say about that on the {{isdaprov|AET}} page.</ref> For example, a [[swap dealer]]’s right to terminate a customer’s [[synthetic equity swap]] position on (longish) notice. If it has such a right, the dealer can treat its equity swap exposures as a “short-term obligation” for capital purposes — because it ''could'' get out, if it ''wanted'' to — and this is enough to get optimised regulatory treatment.


For example, a [[swap dealer]]’s right to terminate a customer’s [[synthetic equity swap]] position on (longish) notice. The dealer can thereby treat its exposure as a “short-term obligation” for capital purposes — because it ''could'' get out, if it ''wanted'' to— and this is enough to get optimised regulatory treatment.  
But a sound-minded dealer ''having'' such a termination right is a different and distant thing from it ever ''exercising'' it. It might be ''forced'' to, in the direst of stress circumstances, where its own survival was threatened — we are in [[Lehman|September 2008]] territory here — but in that case, with the dealer teetering, most vigilant customers would be moving valuable positions away in any case.  


But a sound-minded dealer ''having'' such a termination right is a different and distant thing from it ever ''exercising'' it. It might be ''forced'' to, in the direst of stress circumstances (where its own survival was threatened) — but in that case, with the dealer teetering, most vigilant customers would be moving valuable positions away in any case.
Pseudo-termination rights, in that [[Dealer|dealers]] absolutely must ''have'' them but would never ''use'' them, are a marker of incipient failure in the [[The Victory of Form over Substance|battle between substance and form]]. What matters is that the termination right exists, not that it is ever used. It is sometimes hard to persuade neurotic buy side types that such termination rights are harmless, but in large part they are.
 
Pseudo-termination rights, in that [[dealer|dealers]] absolutely must ''have'' them but would never ''use'' them, are a marker of incipient failure in the [[The Victory of Form over Substance|battle between substance and form]].


====Termination Events====
====Termination Events====
{{drop|I|t is in}} the nature of uncertainty that unwanted things can happen that are no one’s ''fault'', but yet beyond anyone’s power to control or ''stop''. [[Force majeure]] and [[Change in law|changes in law]], [[tax]]ation and [[regulatory capital]] treatment can make the continued provision of a service uneconomic or impractical.
{{drop|I|t is in}} the nature of uncertainty that unwanted things can happen that are no one’s ''fault'', but yet beyond anyone’s power to control or ''stop''. [[Force majeure]] and [[Change in law|changes in law]], [[tax]]ation and [[regulatory capital]] treatment can make the continued provision of a service uneconomic or impractical.


Under the ISDA framework these events are described as {{isdaprov|Termination Event}}s. Typically, they are measured {{isdaprov|Transaction}}-by-{{isdaprov|Transaction}}, so do not shut down ''all'' exposure under the Agreement; only under those {{isdaprov|Transaction}}s which are directly “[[Affected Transaction - ISDA Provision|affected]]”.  
Under the ISDA framework these events are described as {{isdaprov|Termination Event}}s. Typically, they are measured {{isdaprov|Transaction}}-by-{{isdaprov|Transaction}}, so do not shut down ''all'' exposure under the Agreement at once; only under those {{isdaprov|Transaction}}s which are directly “[[Affected Transaction - ISDA Provision|affected]]”.  


Since no one is pointing fingers or swearing, there is generally more leeway for the parties to get heads together and explore workarounds and solutions to avoid termination. An eventual decision to terminate, while regretted, may well arrive during a time of relative psychological calm, ''sans'' malice, and probably even by agreement.
Since no one is pointing fingers or swearing, there is generally more leeway for the parties to get heads together and explore workarounds and solutions to avoid termination. An eventual decision to terminate, while regretted, may well arrive during a time of relative psychological calm, ''sans'' malice, and probably even by agreement.
Line 53: Line 53:


=====Performance failures=====
=====Performance failures=====
Being a contract, the main category of “wicked facts” about your counterparty will be ''things it promised under the contract but did not do'': call these “performance failures”.Direct performance failures — in old money, [[breach of contract|breaches of contract]] — tend not to be controversial: if you think “failing to do a certain something” is an unreasonable ground for terminating a contract, you should not agree to do it in the first place.  
Being a contract, the main category of “wicked facts” about your counterparty justifying termination will be ''things it promised under the contract that did not happen.'' Let us call these “performance failures”. Direct performance failures — in old money, [[Breach of contract|breaches of contract]] — tend not to be controversial: if you think “failing to do a certain something” is an unreasonable ground for terminating a contract, you should not agree to do it in the first place.  


The classic “performance failure” in a [[financial contract]] is a [[failure to pay]]. There could hardly be an obligation more “of the essence” of a [[financial contract]] than rendering in full ''what'' you promised, ''when'' you promised it.  
The classic “performance failure” in a [[financial contract]] is a [[failure to pay]]. There could hardly be an obligation more “of the essence” of a [[financial contract]] than rendering in full ''what'' you promised, ''when'' you promised it.  
Line 59: Line 59:
As a result there is little negotiation of payment failure default events. Nor, when it comes to it, is there much room for doubt as to whether one has happened. The payment either settled or it didn’t. Ops can tell you a few minutes after the cut-off time.
As a result there is little negotiation of payment failure default events. Nor, when it comes to it, is there much room for doubt as to whether one has happened. The payment either settled or it didn’t. Ops can tell you a few minutes after the cut-off time.


Ninety-five per cent of all ISDA close-outs — yes, I ''did'' just make that number up out of thin air, but I challenge you to disprove it — are triggered by a {{isdaprov|Failure to Pay or Deliver}}. It rather makes you wonder why we waste so much time haggling over the rest of the Events of Default.<ref>I put it down to “[[Parkinson’s law of triviality]]”: people spend most of their time attending to complicated things that don't matter, because they are take time and make us feel like we have achieved something. See also [[Qix]]</ref>
Ninety-five per cent of all ISDA close-outs — yes, I ''did'' just make that number up out of thin air, but I challenge anyone to disprove it — are triggered by a {{isdaprov|Failure to Pay or Deliver}}. It rather makes you wonder why we waste so much time haggling over the rest of the Events of Default.<ref>I put it down to “[[Parkinson’s law of triviality]]”: people spend most of their time attending to complicated things that don't matter, because they are take time and make us feel like we have achieved something. See also [[Qix]]</ref>


[[Parkinson’s law of triviality]] exemplified: there is an inverse relationship between ''how long you will have to argue'' about a given close-out right during onboarding and ''how likely you are to ever have to use'' it afterwards.
[[Parkinson’s law of triviality]] exemplified: there is an inverse relationship between ''how long you will have to argue'' about a given termination right during onboarding and ''how likely you are to ever have to use'' it afterwards.


Other direct “performance failures” are a bit more oblique. Technical non-performance measures that are less “essential” than payment failure tend to have longer cure periods: whereas payment failure might have a one-day<ref>Three days under the {{1992ma}}.</ref> [[grace period]], you might have as long as 30 days to put right second-order breaches of an agreement before they become outright {{isdaprov|Events of Default}}.<ref>This makes them useless in practice.</ref>
Other direct “performance failures” are a bit more oblique. Technical non-performance measures that are less “essential” than payment failure tend to have longer cure periods: whereas payment failure might have a one-day<ref>Three days under the {{1992ma}}.</ref> [[grace period]], you might have as long as 30 days to put right less material breaches of an agreement, after being asked to do so, before they become outright {{isdaprov|Events of Default}}. But if a week is a long time in politics, a month is a geological timescale in the capital markets, so this makes less material breaches of contract more or less useless.  


Performance failures that imply bad faith or moral shortcomings, like [[repudiation]], tend not to have [[grace period]]s at all, but seeing as it is quite hard to goad a counterparty into committing one of these, this does not make them any more useful.  
Performance failures that imply bad faith or moral shortcomings, like [[repudiation]], tend not to have [[grace period]]s at all, but seeing as it is quite hard to goad a counterparty into committing one of these, this does not make them any more useful.  
Line 78: Line 78:
| {{isdaprov|Misrepresentation}} || {{isdaprov|5(a)(iv)}} || None.  
| {{isdaprov|Misrepresentation}} || {{isdaprov|5(a)(iv)}} || None.  
{{aligntop}}
{{aligntop}}
| {{isdaprov|Credit Support Default}} (Total failure) || {{isdaprov|5(a)(iii)}}(2)|| None.
| {{isdaprov|Credit Support Default}} (total failure of contract) || {{isdaprov|5(a)(iii)}}(2)|| None.
{{aligntop}}
{{aligntop}}
| {{isdaprov|Failure to Pay or Deliver}} || {{isdaprov|5(a)(i)}} ||One {{isdaprov|Local Business Day}} after due date.
| {{isdaprov|Failure to Pay or Deliver}} || {{isdaprov|5(a)(i)}} ||One {{isdaprov|Local Business Day}} after due date.
Line 89: Line 89:


=====Credit deterioration indicators=====
=====Credit deterioration indicators=====
Depending on how you look at them, there are between three and four ''indirect'' {{isdaprov|Events of Default}} that do not require the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}}’s performance failure directly under the {{isdama}}. These events arise from ''independent'' indications that it might be about to go ''[[titten hoch]]''. These are more fraught, because evidence for them may not be available, if they can be determined at all.
Depending on how you look at them, there are between three and four ''indirect'' {{isdaprov|Events of Default}} that do not require the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}}’s direct performance failure but instead arise from ''independent'' indications that it might be about to go ''[[titten hoch]]''. These are more fraught, because hard evidence may not be readily available to the Non-defaulting Party, if it exists at all.


These are the “credit deterioration” events: {{isdaprov|Default Under Specified Transaction}} — where the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}} has defaulted to the {{isdaprov|Non-defaulting Party}} specifically, only under a separate master trading agreement (such as a stock lending agreement or a repo); {{isdaprov|Cross Default}} — where it has defaulted to someone else altogether under an unrelated [[Borrowed money|borrowing arrangement]] and {{isdaprov|Bankruptcy}}, where the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}} crosses that [[phase transition]] into formal resolution or protection. It didn’t specifically fail under your {{isdama}} but the overwhelming odds are it is about to.
These are the “credit deterioration” events: {{isdaprov|Default Under Specified Transaction}} — where the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}} has failed under a separate master trading agreement to the {{isdaprov|Non-defaulting Party}} specifically; {{isdaprov|Cross Default}} — where it has defaulted to someone else altogether under an unrelated [[Borrowed money|borrowing arrangement]]; and {{isdaprov|Bankruptcy}}, where it has crossed that [[phase transition]] from rude health into formal corporate resolution or protection.  


These events have great potential for the intervention of sod’s law. {{isdaprov|Cross Default}} particularly — JC has a long and overblown article about that — but there are aspects of the {{isdaprov|Bankruptcy}} (especially {{isdaprov|Automatic Early Termination}}) that have the potential for severe unintended consequences.
These events have great potential for the intervention of sod’s law. {{isdaprov|Cross Default}} particularly — JC has a long and overblown article about that — but there are aspects of the {{isdaprov|Bankruptcy}} Event of Default (especially {{isdaprov|Automatic Early Termination}}) that have the potential for severe unintended consequences.


How are you meant to know how great is your customer’s private [[indebtedness]], much less that it has categorically defaulted on it? What if a lender granted a waiver or amendment? Is it still a default?<ref>In JC’s view: no.</ref>
How are you meant to know how much your customer privately owes, much less that it has categorically defaulted? What if a lender granted a waiver or amendment? Is it still a default?<ref>In JC’s view: no.</ref>


These sorts of [[doubt]]s will wrack the credit department. Even senior credit officers will be cowed. A silvery [[SRM|senior relationship manager]], reeking of [[Evyan skin cream and L’Air du Temps|Evyan skin cream and ''L’Air du Temps'']], will storm in, hotly denying ''his'' [[platinum client]] would ever default — that it is sacrilegious even to think things like that. He will have roped in any number of fragrant senior colleagues from the wealth management division to huff outragedly on his client’s behalf. Any firm not populated in its senior echelons by lizards will, wilt before such a dominance display and sit on its hands. (This excludes [[Goldman]], which ''is'' populated in its senior echelons by lizards.<ref>Heh, heh: I’m just kidding fellas. Really. Goldman bankers are no more lizardy than any other investment bankers.</ref>)
These sorts of [[doubt]]s will wrack the credit department. Even senior credit officers will be cowed. A silvery [[SRM|senior relationship manager]], reeking of [[Evyan skin cream and L’Air du Temps|Evyan skin cream and ''L’Air du Temps'']], will storm in, hotly denying ''his'' [[platinum client]] would ever default — that it is sacrilegious even to think things like that. He will have roped in any number of fragrant senior colleagues from the wealth management division to huff outragedly on his client’s behalf. Any firm not populated in its senior echelons by lizards will wilt before such a dominance display and sit on its hands for the minutes of hours it takes for the counterparty to miss its next [[margin call]]. (Except [[Goldman]], which ''is'' populated in its senior echelons by lizards.<ref>Heh, heh: I’m just kidding fellas. Really. Goldman bankers are no more lizardy than any other investment bankers.</ref>)


=====Additional Termination Events=====
=====Additional Termination Events=====
The tailored {{isdaprov|Additional Termination Event}}s your [[credit officer]] would bid you crowbar into the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} tend to have the character of customer-specific ''credit deterioration'' indicators: [[NAV trigger]]s, [[key man risk|key person event]]s, ratings downgrade thresholds and like events that suggest the customer may shortly fail under your contract, even if it hasn’t yet.  
The tailored {{isdaprov|Additional Termination Event}}s your [[credit officer]] would bid you crowbar into the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} tend to have the character of customer-specific ''credit deterioration'' indicators: [[NAV trigger]]s, [[Key man risk|key person event]]s, ratings downgrade thresholds and like events that suggest the customer may shortly fail under your contract, even if it hasn’t yet.
 
These you will spend the ''most'' time haggling about, and by immutable laws of soddery, they will also cause you the most bureaucratic fusspotting afterwards, without ever being of any practical use. For every [[NAV trigger]] you pull, a hundred you will have to gently, and apologetically waive when they are tripped in benign circumstances, lest you be descended on by a gaggle of aromatic [[Senior relationship management|SRM]]<nowiki/>s. Actually, more than that. No one ''ever'' pulls a [[NAV trigger]].


These you will spend the ''most'' time haggling about, and by immutable laws of soddery, they will also cause you the most bureaucratic fusspotting post-execution, without ever being of any practical use. For every [[NAV trigger]] you pull, a hundred you will have to gently, and apologetically waive when they are tripped in benign circumstances. Actually, more than that. No one ''ever'' pulls a [[NAV trigger]].
The real-world life experience of {{isdaprov|ATE}}s — I should say, ''lack'' of experience — tells a counterintuitive story: that [[dealer]]s should not worry too much if a customer rejects their favourite {{isdaprov|ATE}}s; that customers need not worry too much if your dealer won’t back down about the ones it wants, since it will never use it anyway. (Except Goldman. Goldman will ''definitely'' use its ATEs.)


The real-world life experience of {{isdaprov|ATE}}s — I should say, ''lack'' of experience — tell a counterintuitive story: that [[dealer]]s should not worry too much if a customer rejects their favourite {{isdaprov|ATE}}s; that customers need not worry too much if your dealer won’t back down about it, since it will never use it anyway. We all have our roles in the great pantomime.
In any case, we all have our roles in the great pantomime.


=====ISDA in-jokes=====
=====ISDA in-jokes=====
This leaves {{isdaprov|Merger Without Assumption}} — where, through a [[corporate action]] the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}} is transformed into a different legal entity that, through mystical rules of corporate succession, is somehow no longer bound by the {{isdama}} its ancestor signed at all. You might call this a type of “credit deterioration” event, but you could also consider it a direct “performance failure” — an outright ontological ''denial'', almost — under the present contract.
This leaves {{isdaprov|Merger Without Assumption}} — where, through a [[corporate action]] the {{isdaprov|Defaulting Party}} is transformed into a different legal entity that, through mystical rules of corporate succession, is somehow no longer bound by the {{isdama}} its ancestor signed at all. You might call this a type of “credit deterioration” event, but you could also consider it a direct “performance failure” — an outright ontological ''denial'', almost — under the present contract.


As far as I can tell and I checked this with the learned author of {{coc}}, and my young apprentice, and neither put me off the idea — {{isdaprov|Merger Without Assumption}} as articulated in the {{isdama}} is basically a ''practical joke''. A kind of documentary pun, stuck in there at a dark moment in the sacred [[Wording]] in which, to lighten the mood, someone lobbed in this harmless nonsense while fully-armoured ISDA knights wrangled canonical text through the medium of hand-to-hand fighting.  
As far as I can tell, and I checked this with the learned author of {{coc}} and my go-to real-world ISDA ninja — both know a lot more than I do, and neither put me off the idea — {{isdaprov|Merger Without Assumption}} as articulated in the {{isdama}} is basically a ''practical joke''. A kind of documentary pun, stuck in there at a dark moment in the sacred [[Wording]] ritual in which, to lighten the mood, someone lobbed in this harmless nonsense while fully-armoured ISDA knights wrangled canonical text through the medium of hand-to-hand combat. But here we are, nearly thirty years later.  
 
There are few times at which one could plausibly exercise a {{isdaprov|Merger Without Assumption}} against a non-Bankrupt counterparty.
 
 
====Recap====
====Recap====
So, there are three broad means of terminating a financial contract: in order of controversy, on notice, on account of externalities, and following default. When negotiating these rights it is always worth bearing in mind the parties’ respective interests in the contract. An end user wants cheap and reliable exposure to risk. A provider wants cheap and reliable source of commission income. Neither, beyond beating down the other’s expectations about fees, wishes her counterparty ill. We can sand edges off potential rancour by appealing to [[in good faith and a commercially reasonable manner|good faith and commercial reasonableness]]: take a step back and it becomes apparent that is all anyone wants. The nightmarish hypotheticals of your own counsel with a grain of salt: worrying you into haggling suits her own expectations about fees income.  
So, there are three broad means of terminating a financial contract: in order of controversy, on notice, on account of externalities, and following default. When negotiating these rights it is always worth bearing in mind the parties’ respective interests in the contract. An end user wants cheap and reliable exposure to risk. A provider wants cheap and reliable source of commission income. Neither, beyond beating down the other’s expectations about fees, wishes her counterparty ill. We can sand edges off potential rancour by appealing to [[In good faith and a commercially reasonable manner|good faith and commercial reasonableness]]: take a step back and it becomes apparent that is all anyone wants. The nightmarish hypotheticals of your own counsel with a grain of salt: worrying you into haggling suits her own expectations about fees income.  


And of the default events, remember everything comes down to a failure to pay, or a fear of a failure to pay. Those representations, downgrade triggers and key person terms only matter at all to the extent they lead to, or forewarn, a failure to pay.
And of the default events, remember everything comes down to a failure to pay, or a fear of a failure to pay. Those representations, downgrade triggers and key person terms only matter at all to the extent they lead to, or forewarn, a failure to pay.

Revision as of 12:56, 1 November 2024

Commerce gives the lie to the idea that life is a zero-sum game. This was Adam Smith’s great insight: things need not be nasty, brutish and short and, when it comes to commerce, generally aren’t.

Each of us will only strike a bargain if we think, on our own terms, we’ll be better off as a result. That being so, once we’ve built a good business relationship, there is no good reason to end it. All being well, trade is an infinite game. If we are good enough at it, we can keep its positive feedback loop going, for the mutual betterment of everyone, indefinitely. Infinitely, even.

Therefore, we wish our relationships well and pray Godspeed for their long and fruity lives. Should the plums dangling from this or that branch shrivel; if things become more trouble than they’re worth, we can of course call time and bid our relationship a peaceful transition to the hereafter.

But still, things do not always work out quite so equably. Sometimes, an ill wind blows. Relationships become fraught, counterparties get themselves in a pickle.

Therefore, we pack our trunk with tools, implements and weapons with which, if we must, we can engineer a faster exit from our contracts.

There are a few different ways this can happen. While lawyers will happily rabbit on about these hypotheticals in the gruesome specific, we do not talk about them in general terms often enough. So let’s do that now.

Below, we count the types of ways to safely put a commercial relationship in the ground.

Customers and service providers

Now the great majority of financial contracts are between a “provider” on one side — a bank, broker or dealer providing a “service”, broadly described: money outright, finance against an asset or a financial exposure — and a “customer” on the other who pays for that service. The customer is, as ever, king: the service exists for her exclusive benefit: the provider’s only wish is to manage its resources to most efficiently provide that service and extract a fee, commission or economic rent by way of consideration for it.

“Providers” are indifferent to how the instruments they serve perform. They do not mean to be “the other side” of the trade. They are, loosely, intermediaries. Agents. They match risk-takers, collect a fee and wish the parties well without taking sides: they are “compassionate”, not “empathetic”. As long as their customers remain in fine fettle, they should never need, much less want, to terminate their services, for that is how they earn a crust.

But all the same we should note something important here: the expectations of parties to a service contract are very different: the customer takes risk and retains the prerogative to go off risk as she sees fit, as long as she pays the provider’s fees and whatever it needs to terminate the arrangements it made to provide the service in the first place: its “breakage costs”.

But all else being equal, a provider cannot exit a service contract early without the customer’s permission. A fixed term financial contract, binds a provider in a way it does not bind its customer.

As long as the customer remains in good health, no problem. But the customer’s general prospects may darken. She may turn out not to be as good as her word. The regulatory environment may change, making the services harder or more costly to provide. There are times where a service provider may, justifiably, want out.

Where it is no longer sure of its expected return, the provider must have a set of “weapons” it can use to get out of its contracts. These fall into a bunch of different categories, as we shall see.

Put these “termination scenarios” into three categories: without cause; external events and counterparty failure.

Without cause

Terminations “without cause”[1] arise just because — no fault, no pressing need; just a gradual drifting apart of interests. As we grow in life, the things we value change. Passions of youth dampen, we tend more towards scabrous songs of experience than exuberant songs of innocence. If this should mean our commercial paths diverge, we prescribe a notice period long enough to allow each other to make reasonable alternative arrangements, but otherwise, we wish each other well and carry on our way.

“Without cause” termination rights for a service provider will generally be “clean-up” arrangements: to clear out low-value and dormant clientry whose mere presence on the books implies ongoing compliance or operational costs. These rights will not usually impair in-flight Transactions, which a service provider must still see through before it can be allowed to move on.

Pseudo-termination rights

Dealers sometimes must have rights to terminate in-flight customer Transactions on notice without reason. These will often be “pseudo” rights that a dealer must have but will never actually use. These rights help to optimise their liquidity and capital buffers, therefore reducing the dealers’ own costs of doing customer business.[2] For example, a swap dealer’s right to terminate a customer’s synthetic equity swap position on (longish) notice. If it has such a right, the dealer can treat its equity swap exposures as a “short-term obligation” for capital purposes — because it could get out, if it wanted to — and this is enough to get optimised regulatory treatment.

But a sound-minded dealer having such a termination right is a different and distant thing from it ever exercising it. It might be forced to, in the direst of stress circumstances, where its own survival was threatened — we are in September 2008 territory here — but in that case, with the dealer teetering, most vigilant customers would be moving valuable positions away in any case.

Pseudo-termination rights, in that dealers absolutely must have them but would never use them, are a marker of incipient failure in the battle between substance and form. What matters is that the termination right exists, not that it is ever used. It is sometimes hard to persuade neurotic buy side types that such termination rights are harmless, but in large part they are.

Termination Events

It is in the nature of uncertainty that unwanted things can happen that are no one’s fault, but yet beyond anyone’s power to control or stop. Force majeure and changes in law, taxation and regulatory capital treatment can make the continued provision of a service uneconomic or impractical.

Under the ISDA framework these events are described as Termination Events. Typically, they are measured Transaction-by-Transaction, so do not shut down all exposure under the Agreement at once; only under those Transactions which are directly “affected”.

Since no one is pointing fingers or swearing, there is generally more leeway for the parties to get heads together and explore workarounds and solutions to avoid termination. An eventual decision to terminate, while regretted, may well arrive during a time of relative psychological calm, sans malice, and probably even by agreement.

The ISDA Master Agreement allows, too, for customised Additional Termination Events. While these are filed under “Termination Event” they tend to be “defaulty” in nature, so we will deal with them below.

Counterparty failures

Then there are termination rights that flow from something wicked about your counterparty. These the Non-defaulting Party will exercise unilaterally, without so much as a by-your-leave. We might break these down into performance failures, credit deterioration indicators, and ISDA in-jokes.

Performance failures

Being a contract, the main category of “wicked facts” about your counterparty justifying termination will be things it promised under the contract that did not happen. Let us call these “performance failures”. Direct performance failures — in old money, breaches of contract — tend not to be controversial: if you think “failing to do a certain something” is an unreasonable ground for terminating a contract, you should not agree to do it in the first place.

The classic “performance failure” in a financial contract is a failure to pay. There could hardly be an obligation more “of the essence” of a financial contract than rendering in full what you promised, when you promised it.

As a result there is little negotiation of payment failure default events. Nor, when it comes to it, is there much room for doubt as to whether one has happened. The payment either settled or it didn’t. Ops can tell you a few minutes after the cut-off time.

Ninety-five per cent of all ISDA close-outs — yes, I did just make that number up out of thin air, but I challenge anyone to disprove it — are triggered by a Failure to Pay or Deliver. It rather makes you wonder why we waste so much time haggling over the rest of the Events of Default.[3]

Parkinson’s law of triviality exemplified: there is an inverse relationship between how long you will have to argue about a given termination right during onboarding and how likely you are to ever have to use it afterwards.

Other direct “performance failures” are a bit more oblique. Technical non-performance measures that are less “essential” than payment failure tend to have longer cure periods: whereas payment failure might have a one-day[4] grace period, you might have as long as 30 days to put right less material breaches of an agreement, after being asked to do so, before they become outright Events of Default. But if a week is a long time in politics, a month is a geological timescale in the capital markets, so this makes less material breaches of contract more or less useless.

Performance failures that imply bad faith or moral shortcomings, like repudiation, tend not to have grace periods at all, but seeing as it is quite hard to goad a counterparty into committing one of these, this does not make them any more useful.

By order of how quickly you can accelerate them, then, here are the ISDA Master Agreement’s “performance failure” Events of Default:

Itchy Trigger Finger Guide
Event of Default Section Grace period
Repudiation of Agreement 5(a)(ii)(2) (Defaulting Party) or 5(a)(iii)(3) (Credit Support Provider) None.
Misrepresentation 5(a)(iv) None.
Credit Support Default (total failure of contract) 5(a)(iii)(2) None.
Failure to Pay or Deliver 5(a)(i) One Local Business Day after due date.
Breach of Agreement 5(a)(ii)(1) 30 days after notice of default.
Credit Support Default (direct default) 5(a)(iii)(1) Expiry of grace period in Credit Support Document.
Credit deterioration indicators

Depending on how you look at them, there are between three and four indirect Events of Default that do not require the Defaulting Party’s direct performance failure but instead arise from independent indications that it might be about to go titten hoch. These are more fraught, because hard evidence may not be readily available to the Non-defaulting Party, if it exists at all.

These are the “credit deterioration” events: Default Under Specified Transaction — where the Defaulting Party has failed under a separate master trading agreement to the Non-defaulting Party specifically; Cross Default — where it has defaulted to someone else altogether under an unrelated borrowing arrangement; and Bankruptcy, where it has crossed that phase transition from rude health into formal corporate resolution or protection.

These events have great potential for the intervention of sod’s law. Cross Default particularly — JC has a long and overblown article about that — but there are aspects of the Bankruptcy Event of Default (especially Automatic Early Termination) that have the potential for severe unintended consequences.

How are you meant to know how much your customer privately owes, much less that it has categorically defaulted? What if a lender granted a waiver or amendment? Is it still a default?[5]

These sorts of doubts will wrack the credit department. Even senior credit officers will be cowed. A silvery senior relationship manager, reeking of Evyan skin cream and L’Air du Temps, will storm in, hotly denying his platinum client would ever default — that it is sacrilegious even to think things like that. He will have roped in any number of fragrant senior colleagues from the wealth management division to huff outragedly on his client’s behalf. Any firm not populated in its senior echelons by lizards will wilt before such a dominance display and sit on its hands for the minutes of hours it takes for the counterparty to miss its next margin call. (Except Goldman, which is populated in its senior echelons by lizards.[6])

Additional Termination Events

The tailored Additional Termination Events your credit officer would bid you crowbar into the Schedule tend to have the character of customer-specific credit deterioration indicators: NAV triggers, key person events, ratings downgrade thresholds and like events that suggest the customer may shortly fail under your contract, even if it hasn’t yet.

These you will spend the most time haggling about, and by immutable laws of soddery, they will also cause you the most bureaucratic fusspotting afterwards, without ever being of any practical use. For every NAV trigger you pull, a hundred you will have to gently, and apologetically waive when they are tripped in benign circumstances, lest you be descended on by a gaggle of aromatic SRMs. Actually, more than that. No one ever pulls a NAV trigger.

The real-world life experience of ATEs — I should say, lack of experience — tells a counterintuitive story: that dealers should not worry too much if a customer rejects their favourite ATEs; that customers need not worry too much if your dealer won’t back down about the ones it wants, since it will never use it anyway. (Except Goldman. Goldman will definitely use its ATEs.)

In any case, we all have our roles in the great pantomime.

ISDA in-jokes

This leaves Merger Without Assumption — where, through a corporate action the Defaulting Party is transformed into a different legal entity that, through mystical rules of corporate succession, is somehow no longer bound by the ISDA Master Agreement its ancestor signed at all. You might call this a type of “credit deterioration” event, but you could also consider it a direct “performance failure” — an outright ontological denial, almost — under the present contract.

As far as I can tell, and I checked this with the learned author of Cluley on Close-Outs and my go-to real-world ISDA ninja — both know a lot more than I do, and neither put me off the idea — Merger Without Assumption as articulated in the ISDA Master Agreement is basically a practical joke. A kind of documentary pun, stuck in there at a dark moment in the sacred Wording ritual in which, to lighten the mood, someone lobbed in this harmless nonsense while fully-armoured ISDA knights wrangled canonical text through the medium of hand-to-hand combat. But here we are, nearly thirty years later.

Recap

So, there are three broad means of terminating a financial contract: in order of controversy, on notice, on account of externalities, and following default. When negotiating these rights it is always worth bearing in mind the parties’ respective interests in the contract. An end user wants cheap and reliable exposure to risk. A provider wants cheap and reliable source of commission income. Neither, beyond beating down the other’s expectations about fees, wishes her counterparty ill. We can sand edges off potential rancour by appealing to good faith and commercial reasonableness: take a step back and it becomes apparent that is all anyone wants. The nightmarish hypotheticals of your own counsel with a grain of salt: worrying you into haggling suits her own expectations about fees income.

And of the default events, remember everything comes down to a failure to pay, or a fear of a failure to pay. Those representations, downgrade triggers and key person terms only matter at all to the extent they lead to, or forewarn, a failure to pay.

  1. You hear these described as “no-fault” terminations, but there is no fault in a termination brought about by unforeseen externalities, either.
  2. See Automatic Early Termination, which is an extreme example of a pseudo termination right: in that it triggers automatically. Much more to say about that on the AET page.
  3. I put it down to “Parkinson’s law of triviality”: people spend most of their time attending to complicated things that don't matter, because they are take time and make us feel like we have achieved something. See also Qix
  4. Three days under the 1992 ISDA.
  5. In JC’s view: no.
  6. Heh, heh: I’m just kidding fellas. Really. Goldman bankers are no more lizardy than any other investment bankers.