Barter: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
(Created page with "{{a|banking|}}{{d|Barter||n., v|}} In the absence of a common framework for exchange of abstract value, the exchange of one good or service for another. In a particularly entertaining passage is particularly entertaining book, {{br|Debt: The First 5,000 Years}}, the late {{author|David Graeber}} addresses the commonplace wisdom that fiat currency grew out of a system of barter between “savages”. Not only is the necessary widespread “double coincidence” of needs...")
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
 
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Line 8: Line 8:
Where there is evidence of barter was between strangers, and groups between whom trust was low: rival tribes in Papua New Guinean rainforests, shiploads of Her Majesty’s finest colonial oppressors, trading rifles, blankets and influenza for sweet potato, flightless birds and sovereignty.
Where there is evidence of barter was between strangers, and groups between whom trust was low: rival tribes in Papua New Guinean rainforests, shiploads of Her Majesty’s finest colonial oppressors, trading rifles, blankets and influenza for sweet potato, flightless birds and sovereignty.


Money being a only of any use within a community of trust — I say this on. The hoof, but it is hard to see anyone accepting a promissory token in any other circumstances — this presentation of barter as a useful component of a ''trustless'' system rather rules it out of play when it comes to the genealogy of money.
Money being a only of any use within a community of trust — I say this on the hoof, ''[[res ipsa loquitur]]'' and without supporting evidence or argument, but it is hard to see anyone accepting a promissory token offered by a stranger in any other circumstances.
 
Barter is, therefore a local maximum: the best one can do ''in a bad situation, where there is a lack of trust''.  Risk is minimised by restricting exchange to a pre-negotiated swap of goods. (Not goods or ''services'',  because acquiring services in exchange for goods (or services) requires ''trust''.
 
“I understand exactly what I am giving and what I am getting. This is delivery-versus-delivery, at no point am I exposed to this counterpart whom I do not trust.”
 
We reduce the usual scenario of commerce, [[iterated prisoner’s dilemma]] where game theory predicts that provisional trust is the optimal strategy, to a discrete single rounds with ''no'' dilemma. Trust may develop through repeated interaction, but need not. A relationship of “hostile barter” can exist indefinitely, and between adjacent warring factions often does.
 
Where trust does arise, those practical limitations of barter dissolve. Should there be no “double coincidence” one can say to the other, “send the bearskins now, and I will deliver you the arrowheads next week. I memorialise my promise on this written pledge.”
 
This pledge we recognise as an IOU. Banking lawyers, who never use one word when two will do, would call it a [[promissory note]].
 
Something new has happened here: in trusting the arrow maker, the furrier has acquired a new kind of asset: a token representing the promise to deliver arrowheads in the future. This the furrier can keep and present to the arrow maker, but I can also ''sell'' it. She needs arrows now, another merchant has some spare, she will give me hers in exchange


{{Sa}}
{{Sa}}
*[[Bitcoin]]
*[[Bitcoin]]
{{br|Debt: The First 5,000 Years}}
{{br|Debt: The First 5,000 Years}}

Revision as of 08:01, 26 October 2023

Banking basics
A recap of a few things you’d think financial professionals ought to know


Index: Click to expand:

Comments? Questions? Suggestions? Requests? Insults? We’d love to 📧 hear from you.
Sign up for our newsletter.

Barter
(n., v.)
In the absence of a common framework for exchange of abstract value, the exchange of one good or service for another.

In a particularly entertaining passage is particularly entertaining book, Debt: The First 5,000 Years, the late David Graeber addresses the commonplace wisdom that fiat currency grew out of a system of barter between “savages”.

Not only is the necessary widespread “double coincidence” of needs — you want loaves, which I happen to bake, and I happen to want barrels, which you happen to make[1] — that barter implies implausible, says Graeber but, according to the anthropological record (and he was an anthropologist, so well placed to know) there almost no evidence that it happened, at least not within communities with any level of trust or familiarity. The idea that money grew from barter is imaginary, the product of the colourful metaphors of Aristotle, Adam Smith and others.

Where there is evidence of barter was between strangers, and groups between whom trust was low: rival tribes in Papua New Guinean rainforests, shiploads of Her Majesty’s finest colonial oppressors, trading rifles, blankets and influenza for sweet potato, flightless birds and sovereignty.

Money being a only of any use within a community of trust — I say this on the hoof, res ipsa loquitur and without supporting evidence or argument, but it is hard to see anyone accepting a promissory token offered by a stranger in any other circumstances.

Barter is, therefore a local maximum: the best one can do in a bad situation, where there is a lack of trust. Risk is minimised by restricting exchange to a pre-negotiated swap of goods. (Not goods or services, because acquiring services in exchange for goods (or services) requires trust.

“I understand exactly what I am giving and what I am getting. This is delivery-versus-delivery, at no point am I exposed to this counterpart whom I do not trust.”

We reduce the usual scenario of commerce, iterated prisoner’s dilemma where game theory predicts that provisional trust is the optimal strategy, to a discrete single rounds with no dilemma. Trust may develop through repeated interaction, but need not. A relationship of “hostile barter” can exist indefinitely, and between adjacent warring factions often does.

Where trust does arise, those practical limitations of barter dissolve. Should there be no “double coincidence” one can say to the other, “send the bearskins now, and I will deliver you the arrowheads next week. I memorialise my promise on this written pledge.”

This pledge we recognise as an IOU. Banking lawyers, who never use one word when two will do, would call it a promissory note.

Something new has happened here: in trusting the arrow maker, the furrier has acquired a new kind of asset: a token representing the promise to deliver arrowheads in the future. This the furrier can keep and present to the arrow maker, but I can also sell it. She needs arrows now, another merchant has some spare, she will give me hers in exchange

See also

Debt: The First 5,000 Years

  1. This strikes me as a single coincidence, but still.