Mediocrity drift: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Line 3: Line 3:
:— ''[https://www.finews.com/news/english-news/54951-credit-suisse-job-cuts-restructuring-personnel-costsCredit Suisse Job Cuts are Causing Unrest]'',  finews.com, December 2022}}{{d|{{PAGENAME}}|/ˌmiːdɪˈɒkrɪti drɪft/|n}}
:— ''[https://www.finews.com/news/english-news/54951-credit-suisse-job-cuts-restructuring-personnel-costsCredit Suisse Job Cuts are Causing Unrest]'',  finews.com, December 2022}}{{d|{{PAGENAME}}|/ˌmiːdɪˈɒkrɪti drɪft/|n}}


A curious, unintended, negative feedback loop of lazy [[human capital management]]. If you don’t proactively ''retain'' good staff, and if you don’t actively manage out poor staff — if you manage by tactical hiring and “natural attrition” — the general quality of your staff ''relative to their cost'' will ''decline''.
A curious, unintended, negative feedback loop of lazy [[human capital management]]. If you don’t proactively ''retain'' good staff, and if you don’t actively manage out poor staff — if you manage by tactical hiring and “[[natural attrition]]” — the general quality of your staff ''relative to their cost'' will ''decline''.


Let’s say firms, when presented with broadly equivalent candidates, prioritise those of a type it doesn’t have when [[lateral hire|hiring]], and those of which it has too many when selecting candidates for a [[RIF]]. For those who value ''cognitive'' [[diversity]], let alone ''cultural'' diversity, stands to reason.
This is not just your correspondent’s usual curmudgeonly complaint — though it is that, too —but rather is a logical consequence of managing by [[natural attrition]], at least if you accept three general assumptions:


Since one tends to hire one golden strand at a time, but reduce the workforce in large hanks, this creates an odd system effect, predicated on three general assumptions:  
'''Good staff leave by themselves''': Staff with [[lateral quitter|the gumption to leave]] tend to be ''relatively'' good employees, relative to what you pay them.  
*Staff with [[lateral quitter|the gumption to leave]] tend to be ''relatively'' good employees.
 
*Conversely: those who aren’t much chop — who are already overpaid for what they do — are tend not to quit, because they are onto a good thing, would need to find an even more gullible employer to hire them: consequently they will only leave if you make them, by performance management or through a [[RIF]].
'''Bad staff don't''':  Conversely: those who aren’t much chop — who are already overpaid for what they do — tend not to quit, because they are onto a good thing, would need to find an even more gullible employer to hire them: consequently they will only leave if you make them, by performance management or through a [[RIF]].
*That all personnel, however you categorise them, are evenly distributed relative to the [[cost-value threshold]], and that any given subgroup, however classified (except by reference to pure value) will be about as good as any other.  
 
'''Subgroups are normally distributed''': That all personnel, however you categorise them, are evenly distributed relative to the [[cost-value threshold]], and that any given subgroup, however classified (except by reference to pure value) will be about as good as any other.  


So, IT professionals as a group will be as good ''at what they do'' as will lawyers; young as well as old, men as women, and so on. Each group — IT pros, legal eagles, the young, the old, men, women — will ''within their own group'' have broadly similar distributions of outperformers and plodders.  
So, IT professionals as a group will be as good ''at what they do'' as will lawyers; young as well as old, men as women, and so on. Each group — IT pros, legal eagles, the young, the old, men, women — will ''within their own group'' have broadly similar distributions of outperformers and plodders.  

Revision as of 14:33, 21 December 2022

The Human Resources military-industrial complex


The instrument (the “telescreen”, it was called) could be dimmed, but there was no way of shutting it off completely.
Index: Click to expand:

Comments? Questions? Suggestions? Requests? Insults? We’d love to 📧 hear from you.
Sign up for our newsletter.

“The bank emphasizes that staff will also be reduced through natural attrition, not filling vacant positions or offering early retirement.”

Suisse Job Cuts are Causing Unrest, finews.com, December 2022

Mediocrity drift
/ˌmiːdɪˈɒkrɪti drɪft/ (n.)

A curious, unintended, negative feedback loop of lazy human capital management. If you don’t proactively retain good staff, and if you don’t actively manage out poor staff — if you manage by tactical hiring and “natural attrition” — the general quality of your staff relative to their cost will decline.

This is not just your correspondent’s usual curmudgeonly complaint — though it is that, too —but rather is a logical consequence of managing by natural attrition, at least if you accept three general assumptions:

Good staff leave by themselves: Staff with the gumption to leave tend to be relatively good employees, relative to what you pay them.

Bad staff don't: Conversely: those who aren’t much chop — who are already overpaid for what they do — tend not to quit, because they are onto a good thing, would need to find an even more gullible employer to hire them: consequently they will only leave if you make them, by performance management or through a RIF.

Subgroups are normally distributed: That all personnel, however you categorise them, are evenly distributed relative to the cost-value threshold, and that any given subgroup, however classified (except by reference to pure value) will be about as good as any other.

So, IT professionals as a group will be as good at what they do as will lawyers; young as well as old, men as women, and so on. Each group — IT pros, legal eagles, the young, the old, men, women — will within their own group have broadly similar distributions of outperformers and plodders.

If so, then a system which favours one group (group A) over another (group B) has a counterintuitive effect on the remaining populations of both groups: on average, the unfavoured group will increase in relative value, and the favoured group will decrease in relative value, even though no individual performance, in either group, changes at all.

On a second glance, you can see why this should be so. The process systematically weeds out underperforming members of group B and overperforming members of group A. The “good” side of the distribution will progressively become group B-dominated — they are not being bid away as frequently — and the “below par” section will becomes progressively group A dominated, as poor performing group B members are selected for eradication.

Two observations: firstly, here is systemantics in its raw natural state; and secondly, notice how pernicious the idea of the average is here.

On average, the group A is paid progressively less. It looks like group A members are being systematically discriminated against on pay, but this is not so (in this model, no-one’s pay changes) in fact group A members are being favoured for poor performance.

How your incoming lateral hires perform will remain to be seen but, remember, performance is measured relative to cost. Since by leaving they have marked themselves to market, overperformers leave their old slot in the quincunx where they were at the top, and enter their new quincunx at the median. The vicissitudes of random chance mean the new arrivals might wind up in any slot but, in any case, their slot on average will be normally distributed. Your arriving at a higher cost than the ones you are replacing, they start not as outlier good staff, but average ones.

See also