Seeing Like a State: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
 
(28 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|book review|
{{a|book review|
[[File:North Korea.jpg|450px|thumb|center|A weekly [[stakeholder]] work-stream check-in call, yesterday.]]
{{image|North Korea|jpg|A weekly [[stakeholder]] [[work-stream]] check-in call, yesterday.}}{{bi}}
}}{{br|Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed}} — {{author|James C. Scott}}<br>
}}{{br|Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed}} — {{author|James C. Scott}}<br>
{{Quote|No battle — Tarutino, Borodino, or Austerlitz — takes place as those who planned it anticipated. That is an essential condition.
{{Quote|''No battle — Tarutino, Borodino, or Austerlitz — takes place as those who planned it anticipated. That is an essential condition.''
:—Tolstoy, ''War and Peace''}}
:—Tolstoy, ''War and Peace''}}
{{quote|
{{Quote|Business, and government, suffers from a kind of physics envy.
:—{{author|James C. Scott}}
:—{{author|Rory Sutherland}}, citing Paul Ormerod}}
This one goes to the top of [[JC]]’s 2020 lockdown re-reads. It was published in 1998, so it’s a bit late to get excited — but while it addresses the “[[high modernism]]” of 20th Century government, the read-across to the capitalist market economy, and beyond that into the interior workings of ''any'' large corporation — are you reading, boss?<ref>Boss: “Yes, [[JC]], I am. Now, [[get your coat]].”</ref> — shrieks from every page. These are profound ideas we all ''should'' recognise, and which could transform the effectiveness of what we all do, but — being, well, citizens of a “prostrate civil society” — either we can’t or we ’’won’t.’’
{{quote|''In sum, the [[legibility]] of a society provides the capacity for large-scale social engineering, [[high-modernist]] ideology provides the desire, the authoritarian state provides the determination to act on that de­sire, and an incapacitated civil society provides the leveled social ter­rain on which to build.''
:—{{author|James C. Scott}}}}
{{drop|J|ames C. Scott}} published {{br|Seeing Like a State}} nearly thirty years ago, in 1998, so it’s a bit late to get excited about it and while it addresses a form of “[[high modernism]]” that saw its apex in the late 20th Century, the read-across to our encroaching technocratic dystopia, and beyond it into the interior workings of ''any'' large corporation shrieks from every page.  


Exactly ''why'' there is this collective affliction of [[wilful blindness]] to our administrative compulsion is a great, unexplored topic of our age. That so many, great and small, have so much to lose by exploring it may explain the mystery.
These are profound ideas we all ''should'' recognise, and which could transform the effectiveness of what we all do, but — being, well, citizens of a “prostrate civil society” — either we can’t or we ''won’t''.


{{br|Seeing Like a State}} takes as its thesis how well-intended patrician government can, in some circumstances, lead to utter disaster. While Scott’s examples are legion, one could — and some do — criticise him for his anecdotal approach: he has curated examples that best fit his thesis, and it therefore suffers from insoluble [[confirmation bias]]. That may be true, but I don’t think it matters, for Scott’s thesis is so ''familiar'', so ''plausible'' and its exhortations so consistent with other theories in adjacent fields,<ref>{{author|Charles Perrow}}’s {{br|Normal Accidents}} theory; [[Systems Theory]] as expounded by {{author|Donella H. Meadows}}, {{author|Thomas Kuhn}}’s {{br|The Structure of Scientific Revolutions}}</ref> that it is hard to be bothered by a lack of empirical rigour. This stuff all stands to reason. Data is not its value: Scott’s ''[[narrative]]'' is its value, as a counter-narrative to modern statist (and corporate) orthodoxy, and that in itself is valuable and enlightening.  
Exactly ''why'' we are so wilfully blind to this ''will to administration'' is the great, unexplored topic of our age. That so many have so much to lose by exploring it may explain the mystery.


In any case, bureaucratic disaster is not inevitable, but the same four conditions are present wherever we find it: a will to bend nature, and society, to the administrator’s agenda; a [[high modernism|“high modernist” ideology]] believing that all problems can be anticipated and solved ahead of time; an authoritarian state with machinery to impose its ideological vision; and a subjugated citizenry (or staff) without the means (or inclination) to resist the machinery of the administrator.
Scott’s thesis in {{br|Seeing Like a State}} is that well-meant patrician government can lead to utter disaster. His examples are legion. One could — and some do — criticise him for this anecdotal approach: he has, on this view, curated examples that best fit his thesis, which therefore suffers from insoluble [[confirmation bias]] — but this barely matters, for Scott’s thesis is so ''familiar'', so ''plausible'' and its exhortations so consistent with other theories in adjacent fields,<ref>{{author|Charles Perrow}}’s {{br|Normal Accidents}} theory; [[systems theory]] as expounded by {{author|Donella H. Meadows}}, {{author|Thomas Kuhn}}’s {{br|The Structure of Scientific Revolutions}}</ref> that it is hard to be bothered by a lack of empirical rigour. ''This stuff all stands to reason.''


''All'' of these qualities feature in the modern multinational corporation. If you are interested in how ''not'' to run one, {{br|Seeing Like a State}} is worth a close read.
Its value is not in its data but Scott’s ''[[narrative]]'', as a counter-narrative to the modern corporate orthodoxy, that some gilded superman at the top of the heap pulling magic levers can do so for the betterment of all.  


===[[Legibility]]: the administrative ordering of nature and society ===
Scott does not say that disaster follows inevitably from top-down management, but just that it is a likely [[system effect]]. Wherever there is a disaster, the same four conditions are present: {{L1}}
Any government must be able to “read” and thus “get a handle on” hence, “make [[legible]]” — and so ''administrate'' the vast sprawling ''detail'' and myriad of ''interconnections'' between its citizens, lands and resources. It does this by, in its “statey” way, [[Narrative|narratising]] a bafflingly [[complex system]] into a thin, idealistic model: it assigns its citizens permanent identities (in the middle ages, literally, by giving them surnames: now, identity cards and the chips that are shortly to be implanted in our foreheads); it decrees standard weights and measures for all times and places (we may have proceeded by local customs and conventions;<ref>It is said Chinese farmers gauged distance by “the time it takes to boil rice”, which provides a different, and more practical means of comprehending how far away you are</ref> commissions cadastral surveys of the land so it can collect taxes; it records land holdings, registers births, deaths and marriages, imposes conventions of language and legal discourse designs cities and transport networks: in effect, to create a standard grid that could be measured, monitored and understood from the bird’s eye view of city hall. A population that legible is ''manipulable''.
The will to bend nature — and the polity to the administrator’s agenda<li>
a [[high modernism|“high modernist” ideology]] under which all problems can be anticipated and solved with the right organisation, application and empirical rigour<li>
the authoritarian machinery to impose this ideological vision and <li>
a subjugated citizenry without the means or inclination to resist.</ol>


This cost of this legibility is ''abridgement'': it represents only the slice of society that interests the administrator, which would be harmless enough those measures did not in turn permanently impact how citizens interact with each other and their environment. So, society came to be ''remade'' to suit the administrator. Thus, a reflexive feedback loop.
Stalin’s Russia, Mao’s China and Kim’s North Korea fit the pattern exactly. ''But so do most modern multinational corporations''. In what follows, “government” may be interchanged with “executive management” with little loss of sense.


Scott is persuasive that we lose something critical when we simplify in our yen for clear description, which state officials cannot but do. Trying to covert local customs — “a living, negotiated tissue of practices which are continually being adapted to new ecological and social circumstances including, of course, power relations” — to unalterable laws loses subtlety and micro-adjustments that these customs are continually experiencing.
====Legibility: the administrative ordering of nature and society====
{{drop|A|ny government}} must be able to “read” and thus “get a handle on” hence, “make [[legible]]” — and so ''administrate'' the vast sprawling ''detail'' and myriad ''interconnections'' between its citizens, lands and resources.  


In other words, you lose something special when you atomise a [[complex system]]. [[Emergence|Emergent]] properties vanish. It is a poorer, less productive thing.
It does this by, in its “statey” way, [[Narrative|narratising]] a bafflingly [[complex system]] into a thin, idealistic model: it assigns its citizens permanent identities (in the Middle Ages, literally, by giving them surnames: now, with identity cards, passports and, er, the chips shortly to be implanted in our foreheads); it decrees standard weights, measures and distances for times and places overruling local customs and conventions (it is said Chinese farmers gauged distance by “the time it takes to boil rice”, which provides a different, and more practical means of comprehending how far away you are); it commissions “cadastral surveys” of the land so it can collect taxes; it records land holdings, registers births, deaths and marriages, imposes conventions of language and legal discourse, designs cities and transport networks: in effect, it creates a standard grid that can be measured, monitored and understood from the bird’s eye view of city hall. A population that [[legible]] is ''manipulable''.  


===[[High modernism|High modernist ideology]]===
This cost of this legibility is ''abridgement'': it represents only the slice of society that interests the administrator. This would be harmless enough if those measures did not impact how citizens interact with each other and their environment. But, as we know they do.
When your yen to regularise society is accompanied by the “muscle-bound” self-confidence that you can expand production, better satisfy human needs and master nature (including human nature) and centrally configure social order “commensurate with the scientific understanding of natural laws”. It translates to a rational, ordered, geometric (hence “legible”) view of the word and depends on central state vision to bring about big projects. Now those infinitesimal interconnections and illegible relations are not just invisible to the state programme but inimical to it. Natural forests are replaced with grid-planted Norfolk pines and swathes of the unwanted ecosystem are rejected ''because they don’t fit the model''. But they can play valuable and vital roles in the ecosystem. The simplistic deterministic belief that they are not necessary will eventually come back to haunt you. “Nature,as Dr. Ian Malcolm put it in ''Jurassic Park'', “finds a way”.


The [[high modernism|high modernist]] believes the future is somehow solvable and certain, and the [[certainty]] of that better future justifies the disruption and short-term adverse side-effects of putting in place a grand plan to get there. The counterpoint to this approach is the [[iterative]], ground-up organic adjustment of people on the ground, using their judgment and experience to best improve the lot as they personally see it. As long as you have the right people on the ground, this is both far more effective for society, and far ''scarier'' for administrators: they have less ''control'' over progress, less ''sight'' of it, (therefore) less to do, and a harder job justifying the rent they extract (in a government, this is called a “tax”; in a corporation, it is executive [[compensation]]) for providing their “vital” administration.<ref>It is of course a heresy to question it, but is any [[CEO]] ''really'' worth a hundred times the average employee that the firm pays for him?</ref>
Citizens account for their incomes to optimise their personal tax positions. When administrators levied a window tax — reasoning that the number of windows is proportionate to the size of a building, and therefore a fair [[proxy]] — citizens redesigned their houses to have fewer windows. This brought in less tax and harmed the well-being of the population.


{{Quote|''Once the desire for comprehensive urban planning is established, the logic of uniformity and regimentation is well nigh inexorable. Cost effectiveness contributes to this tendency. Every concession to diversity is likely to entail an increase in time and budgetary cost.''}}
Modern society is shot through with similar arbitrary rules. Through their combined effect society comes to be ''remade'' to suit the administrator, but not always in ways the administrator might have had in mind. Society is the archetypal [[system]]: arbitrarily diverting its natural stocks and flows to solve one administrative problem inevitably only creates other feedback loops generating other ones.  


Another cost of the [[high modernist]] ideology that seeks to regularise and unitise is ''[[diversity]]'' in the things so regularised.  
We lose something critical when we simplify, which state officials cannot but do. Converting local customs — “a living, negotiated tissue of practices which are continually being adapted to new ecological and social circumstances — including, of course, power relations” — to unalterable [[thin rules]] loses the subtlety and scope for micro-adjustment — evolution — that these customs, if left to themselves, continually undergo.


That [[diversity and inclusion]] is the ''cause célèbre du jour'', in the public and private sectors, hardly [[Falsification|falsifies]] this observation. It just sharpens the irony, since the typical approach to ''delivering'' diversity chimes with this desire for narratising [[legibility]] and [[high-modernism]].  
You lose something special when you [[Financialisation|atomise]] a [[complex system]]. [[Emergence|Emergent]] properties vanish. It is a poorer, less productive thing.


[[Diversity]] ought, you’d think, to be ''hard to pin down'', its manifestations being naturally — well — ''diverse''. But to get a handle on [[diversity]] in their populations, organisations must make [[diversity]] ''[[legible]]''. They do this by defining it in a strikingly limited, and curiously homogenous, way. They seeking to gather ''data'' from their staff on that limited metric — to make it more [[legible]], so that the organisation can propagate statistics about its “improving” [[diversity]]. Thus, “[[diversity]]” as the administration knows it is a formalised, homogenised, parameterised and regularised [[second-order derivative]], and no attention is paid to the outcome of this diversity (compared with the illegible diversity it replaced) at all. As long as the firm ''looks'' diverse, and ''talks'' like it’s diverse, and everyone fits neatly, in the mandated proportions, into one of the five boxes it has prescribed for them, it has achieved its goal.  
====High modernist ideology====
{{drop|T|his yen to}} ''regularise'' often comes with a “muscle-bound” self-confidence that the State can expand production, better satisfy human needs and master nature (including human nature) and centrally configure social order “commensurate with the scientific understanding of natural laws”. This is the “[[high-modernist]]” view. It translates to a rational, ordered, geometric (hence “legible”) view of a world which depends on the benign guiding vision of the state to bring about big projects.  


Sounds a bit like an Aldous Huxley novel, doesn’t it? Feels a bit like one too.
Now those infinitesimal interconnections and illegible relations are not just “''invisible''” to the State, but ''inimical'' to it. Natural forests are replaced with grid plantations of Norway spruce: it rejects parts of the ecosystem because it cannot “see” them and ''because they don’t fit the model''. But those invisible parts play valuable and vital roles in the ecosystem — even for the Norway spruce.
 
{{quote|A new term, ''Waldsterben'' (“forest death”), entered the German vocab­ulary to describe the worst cases. An exceptionally complex process in­volving soil building, nutrient uptake, and symbiotic relations among fungi, insects, mammals, and flora — which were, and still are, not en­tirely understood — was apparently disrupted, with serious conse­quences. Most of these consequences can be traced to the radical sim­plicity of the scientific forest.}}
 
The [[deterministic]] belief that these “illegible” details — in this case, literally, “[[in the weeds]]” — don’t matter will eventually come back to haunt you. “Nature,” as Dr. Ian Malcolm put it in ''Jurassic Park'', “finds a way”.
 
But the [[high modernism|high modernist]] believes the future is solvable, and the ''[[certainty]]'' of that better future justifies the disruption and “short-term side-effects” of the grand plan to get there.
 
The alternative is an [[iterative]], ground-up, organic management by those on the ground — you know, ''us'' — who are best placed and best incentivised to use judgment and experience to solve their own problems and improve their own lot as they personally perceive it.
 
Their “read” of the landscape will be necessarily far richer and more detailed than the State’s. This is both far more effective for society, and far ''scarier'' for administrators: they have less ''control'' over progress, less ''sight'' of it, (therefore) less to do, and a harder job justifying the [[Rent-seeking|rent]] they extract (in a government, this is called a “tax”; in a corporation, it is executive [[compensation]]) for providing their “vital” administration.
 
{{Quote|''Once the desire for comprehensive urban planning is established, the logic of uniformity and regimentation is well nigh inexorable. Cost-effectiveness contributes to this tendency. Every concession to diversity is likely to entail an increase in time and budgetary cost.''}}
====Diversity====
{{drop|A|nother cost of}} this ideology is ''[[diversity]]'' in the things so regularised. That [[diversity and inclusion]] is the ''cause célèbre du jour'', in the public and private sectors, sharpens the irony: since the typical approach to ''delivering'' diversity chimes with this desire for narratising [[legibility]] and [[high-modernism]].
 
[[Diversity]] ought, you’d think, to be hard to pin down, its manifestations being naturally — well — ''diverse''. It is the very benefit that accrues from the range of our differences and the interaction of our unique perspectives and lived experiences.
 
But, to get a handle it, organisations must make [[diversity]] ''[[legible]]''. They do this by defining it in a limited and homogenous way. They gather ''data'' from their staff on that limited metric — to make it more [[legible]], so that the organisation can propagate statistics about its “improving” [[diversity]]. Thus, “[[diversity]]” as the administration knows it is a formalised, homogenised, parameterised and regularised ''[[proxy]]'' of [[diversity]], and no attention is paid to how this [[proxy]] [[diversity]] affects the behaviour of people in the organisation, for good or ill.
 
In any case, the point is clear: if imposed proxies can prompt the wealthy to restructure their tax affairs and French peasants to fill in their windows, so can it prompt those in a commercial organisation to behave in similarly counterproductive ways. There is an argument that whole segments of the infrastructure have developed for precisely that reason. [[Legal]] included.  


===An authoritarian state and prostrate civil society===
===An authoritarian state and prostrate civil society===
Scott’s last two criteria are probably opposite sides of the same coin: an authoritarian state, able and willing to coerce the society it manages to bring its [[high modernist]] ideals into being, and a subjugated population lacking the capacity to resist the implementation of these plans.  
{{drop|S|cott’s last two}} criteria are opposite sides of the same coin: an authoritarian state that can coerce the society it manages to bring its [[high modernist]] ideals to bear, and a subjugated population that cannot resist it.
 
Scott was writing in 1998, a few years after the collapse of communism, when [[This time it’s different|Francis Fukuyama]] and others were declaring [[The End of History and the Last Man|the end of history, the last man]], all battles won and so forth, so was a little shoe-shuffly about this. He needn’t have been: not only have we seen the return of authoritarian governments and prostrate populations — the entire planet suffered eighteen months of solitary confinement without a great deal of complaint let us not forget — and the authoritarian disposition amongst the executive class and the supine one amongst the general population have ''always'' been a feature of the corporate sector.
 
Every “meaningful” aspect of your performance and your role is reduced to a data point: ID, location, salary, rank, position, performance, reporting line, holiday entitlement, sick leave, [[service catalog]], performance objectives. All the work you do: the subtle analysis, the advocacy, the creative solutions, the informal network and ineffable judgments — all is, in the eyes of the executive, reduced to a ''grade'', a ''rank'' and a ''number''.
 
As for the [[high modernist]] ideal, well, this entire site is ironic homage to that, but orthodox “business strategy” presumes we can solve all conundrums in the landscape and then proceed sedately and without the need to be troubled by turbulent [[subject matter expert]]s thereafter.
 
====Metis====
{{drop|T|alk of subject}} [[subject matter expert|matter experts]] brings us nicely to Scott’s closing, where he introduces the concept, missing from the high modernist canon, of ''[[metis]]''.  


Scott was writing in 1998, a few years after the collapse of communism and in an era when [[This time it’s different|Francis Fukuyama]] and others were declaring the end of history, all battles won and so forth, so was a little shoe-shuffly about this. He needn’t have been! Not only have we since seen the return of authoritarian governments and prostrate populations — for posterity, I write from the ninth month of a government-mandated nationwide lockdown — but it has ''always'' been true of the corporate sector, which is resolutely organised to be maximally authoritarian and hierarchical and where you, dear employee, are administrated and ordered like no other participant on Earth.  
This is hard to describe — folk wisdom, knowhow, Odyssean cunning, experience — but in the corporate world it struck me as most resembling ''[[subject matter expert|expertise]]''. Ingenuity, [[Problem solving|problem-solving]], lateral thinking; smarts for figuring out what to do on the fly if you are in a jam.  


Every “meaningful”<ref>Meaningful to them, not to you.</ref> aspect of your performance and your role is, at some level, reduced to a parameterised data point: ID, location, salary, rank, position, performance, reporting line, holiday entitlement, sick-leave, [[service catalog]], objectives — let me know when you want me to stop. As for the [[high modernist]] ideal, well, this entire site is a paean to that, but “strategy” as we mutely receive it, seems entirely predicated on a [[reductionist]] ideology that we can solve all conundrums in our landscape and then proceed sedately and without the need to be troubled by turbulent [[subject matter expert]]s thereafter.
It is something that [[high modernist|high modernists]] would ''abolish''— their theory being that [[Subject matter expert|loose cannon employees]] making snap decisions is potentially catastrophic. Jams of this sort can and should be avoided by appropriate planning and the right algorithm: if you get the playbook right, subject matter experts aren’t needed.  


Given our recent history you would think our overlords ought to know better than that.
Scott makes two interesting observations here. The first is that “[[metis]]” is much more ''efficient'' than an algorithm, even if you can find one to work. This is why (''pace'' dear old [[Richard Dawkins]]) we catch flying baseballs not by solving differential equations in our heads, but by using the “gaze heuristic”.<ref>[[Gerd Gigerenzer]] is fantastic on this.</ref> You could — if you accept the [[reductionist]] stance — solve any problem with the right calculations, but the necessary data and processing power would be ''huge''. Practical knowledge, on the other hand — [[metis]] — is “as economical and accurate as it needs to be, no more and no less, for addressing the problem at hand.


===[[Metis]]===
This is the difference, says Scott, between Red Adair<ref>Younger readers may not remember Red Adair but in the Seventies, he was a {{plainlink|https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Red_Adair|proper Boys’ Own fire-fighting hero}}. </ref> and an articled clerk. There are some skills you ''cannot'' acquire except through experience: learning to sail, ride a bike, play a musical instrument or ''extinguish a civilisation-threatening oil well fire''. You could spend as much time as you like with textbooks, but you will never master that kind of skill until you have done enough practical rehearsal.
Speaking of [[subject matter expert]]s brings us nicely to Scott’s  closing, where he ruminates on the concept, missing from high modernist canon, of ''[[metis]]''. This is hard to describe — folk wisdom, knowhow, Odyssean cunning — but in the corporate world it struck me as most resembling ''[[subject matter expert|expertise]]''. Ingenuity, [[Problem solving|problem-solving]], lateral thinking; smarts for figuring out what to do on the fly if you are in a jam. This is something that the [[high modernist]] programme seeks abolish — the theory being that [[Subject matter expert|loose cannon employees]] wandering around making snap decisions is potentially catastrophic, and jams of this sort can and should be avoided by appropriate planning: thus, [[subject matter expert]]s aren’t needed.  


There are two interesting observations here. The first is that [[metis]] is much more ''efficient''. You could — if you accept the reductionist stance — solve any problem with the right calculations, but the necessary data and processing power would be huge: but practical knowledge — [[metis]] — is “as economical and accurate as it needs to be, no more and no less, for addressing the problem at hand.
This brings us to the last connection: [[complexity theory]], [[systems analysis]] and [[normal accident]]s.


This is the difference, says Scott, between Red Adair<ref>Younger readers may not remember this [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Red_Adair legend of the fire-fighting community]. </ref> and an articled clerk. There are some skills you cannot acquire except through experience. Likewise, learning to sail, ride a bike, or play a musical instrument. You could spend as much time as you like with textbooks, but you will never master riding a bike until you have done enough practical rehearsal.
All of these come to the same conclusion: if you are dealing with tightly-coupled complex systems that interact in non-linear ways, no matter how much data you have or how sophisticated are your tools, mindless algorithms will not work. The only way to manage these risks is with experts on the ground, whom you empower to exercise judgment and make provisional decisions, which they can adjust as a situation unfolds. That is, with their ''[[metis]]''.  


Which brings us to the last connection: that to [[complexity theory]], [[systems analysis]] and [[normal accident]]s theory. All of these come to the same conclusion: if you are dealing with [[complex systems]], especially [[tightly-coupled]] ones with [[non-linear]] interactions, you ''cannot'' solve these with [[algorithm|algorithms]], no matter how much data and no matter how sophisticated is your conceptual scheme. The ''only'' way to manage these risks is with experts on the ground, who are empowered to exercise their judgment and make provisional decisions, and to adjust them as a situation unfolds. That is, with [[metis]]. If your conceptual scheme has systematically eliminated [[metis]] from your operation, you may carry on in times of peace and equability, but should a crisis come, you are ''stuffed''.
If, in your high-modernist zeal, you have eliminated all those with metis from your operation, you may get by in times of peace and equity but, come the revolution, you are stuffed.


{{sa}}
{{sa}}
*{{br|Models.Behaving.Badly: Why Confusing Illusion with Reality can be a Disaster, on Wall Street and in Life}}
*{{br|Thinking in Systems}} — {{author|Donella H. Meadows}}
*{{br|Normal Accidents: Living with High-Risk Technologies}}
*{{br|Models.Behaving.Badly: Why Confusing Illusion with Reality can be a Disaster, on Wall Street and in Life}} — {{author|Emanuel Derman}}
*{{br|Normal Accidents: Living with High-Risk Technologies}} — {{author|Charles Perrow}}
*[[The map and the territory]]
*[[Diversity]]
*[[Diversity]]
{{ref}}
{{ref}}
{{Book Club Wednesday|20/1/21}}
{{C|Systems theory}}

Latest revision as of 16:34, 5 November 2024

The Jolly Contrarian’s book review service™


A weekly stakeholder work-stream check-in call, yesterday.
Index: Click to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have FailedJames C. Scott

No battle — Tarutino, Borodino, or Austerlitz — takes place as those who planned it anticipated. That is an essential condition.

—Tolstoy, War and Peace

Business, and government, suffers from a kind of physics envy.

Rory Sutherland, citing Paul Ormerod

In sum, the legibility of a society provides the capacity for large-scale social engineering, high-modernist ideology provides the desire, the authoritarian state provides the determination to act on that de­sire, and an incapacitated civil society provides the leveled social ter­rain on which to build.

James C. Scott

James C. Scott published Seeing Like a State nearly thirty years ago, in 1998, so it’s a bit late to get excited about it — and while it addresses a form of “high modernism” that saw its apex in the late 20th Century, the read-across to our encroaching technocratic dystopia, and beyond it into the interior workings of any large corporation shrieks from every page.

These are profound ideas we all should recognise, and which could transform the effectiveness of what we all do, but — being, well, citizens of a “prostrate civil society” — either we can’t or we won’t.

Exactly why we are so wilfully blind to this will to administration is the great, unexplored topic of our age. That so many have so much to lose by exploring it may explain the mystery.

Scott’s thesis in Seeing Like a State is that well-meant patrician government can lead to utter disaster. His examples are legion. One could — and some do — criticise him for this anecdotal approach: he has, on this view, curated examples that best fit his thesis, which therefore suffers from insoluble confirmation bias — but this barely matters, for Scott’s thesis is so familiar, so plausible and its exhortations so consistent with other theories in adjacent fields,[1] that it is hard to be bothered by a lack of empirical rigour. This stuff all stands to reason.

Its value is not in its data but Scott’s narrative, as a counter-narrative to the modern corporate orthodoxy, that some gilded superman at the top of the heap pulling magic levers can do so for the betterment of all.

Scott does not say that disaster follows inevitably from top-down management, but just that it is a likely system effect. Wherever there is a disaster, the same four conditions are present:

  1. The will to bend nature — and the polity — to the administrator’s agenda
  2. a “high modernist” ideology under which all problems can be anticipated and solved with the right organisation, application and empirical rigour
  3. the authoritarian machinery to impose this ideological vision and
  4. a subjugated citizenry without the means or inclination to resist.

Stalin’s Russia, Mao’s China and Kim’s North Korea fit the pattern exactly. But so do most modern multinational corporations. In what follows, “government” may be interchanged with “executive management” with little loss of sense.

Legibility: the administrative ordering of nature and society

Any government must be able to “read” and thus “get a handle on” — hence, “make legible” — and so administrate the vast sprawling detail and myriad interconnections between its citizens, lands and resources.

It does this by, in its “statey” way, narratising a bafflingly complex system into a thin, idealistic model: it assigns its citizens permanent identities (in the Middle Ages, literally, by giving them surnames: now, with identity cards, passports and, er, the chips shortly to be implanted in our foreheads); it decrees standard weights, measures and distances for times and places overruling local customs and conventions (it is said Chinese farmers gauged distance by “the time it takes to boil rice”, which provides a different, and more practical means of comprehending how far away you are); it commissions “cadastral surveys” of the land so it can collect taxes; it records land holdings, registers births, deaths and marriages, imposes conventions of language and legal discourse, designs cities and transport networks: in effect, it creates a standard grid that can be measured, monitored and understood from the bird’s eye view of city hall. A population that legible is manipulable.

This cost of this legibility is abridgement: it represents only the slice of society that interests the administrator. This would be harmless enough if those measures did not impact how citizens interact with each other and their environment. But, as we know they do.

Citizens account for their incomes to optimise their personal tax positions. When administrators levied a window tax — reasoning that the number of windows is proportionate to the size of a building, and therefore a fair proxy — citizens redesigned their houses to have fewer windows. This brought in less tax and harmed the well-being of the population.

Modern society is shot through with similar arbitrary rules. Through their combined effect society comes to be remade to suit the administrator, but not always in ways the administrator might have had in mind. Society is the archetypal system: arbitrarily diverting its natural stocks and flows to solve one administrative problem inevitably only creates other feedback loops generating other ones.

We lose something critical when we simplify, which state officials cannot but do. Converting local customs — “a living, negotiated tissue of practices which are continually being adapted to new ecological and social circumstances — including, of course, power relations” — to unalterable thin rules loses the subtlety and scope for micro-adjustment — evolution — that these customs, if left to themselves, continually undergo.

You lose something special when you atomise a complex system. Emergent properties vanish. It is a poorer, less productive thing.

High modernist ideology

This yen to regularise often comes with a “muscle-bound” self-confidence that the State can expand production, better satisfy human needs and master nature (including human nature) and centrally configure social order “commensurate with the scientific understanding of natural laws”. This is the “high-modernist” view. It translates to a rational, ordered, geometric (hence “legible”) view of a world which depends on the benign guiding vision of the state to bring about big projects.

Now those infinitesimal interconnections and illegible relations are not just “invisible” to the State, but inimical to it. Natural forests are replaced with grid plantations of Norway spruce: it rejects parts of the ecosystem because it cannot “see” them and because they don’t fit the model. But those invisible parts play valuable and vital roles in the ecosystem — even for the Norway spruce.

A new term, Waldsterben (“forest death”), entered the German vocab­ulary to describe the worst cases. An exceptionally complex process in­volving soil building, nutrient uptake, and symbiotic relations among fungi, insects, mammals, and flora — which were, and still are, not en­tirely understood — was apparently disrupted, with serious conse­quences. Most of these consequences can be traced to the radical sim­plicity of the scientific forest.

The deterministic belief that these “illegible” details — in this case, literally, “in the weeds” — don’t matter will eventually come back to haunt you. “Nature,” as Dr. Ian Malcolm put it in Jurassic Park, “finds a way”.

But the high modernist believes the future is solvable, and the certainty of that better future justifies the disruption and “short-term side-effects” of the grand plan to get there.

The alternative is an iterative, ground-up, organic management by those on the ground — you know, us — who are best placed and best incentivised to use judgment and experience to solve their own problems and improve their own lot as they personally perceive it.

Their “read” of the landscape will be necessarily far richer and more detailed than the State’s. This is both far more effective for society, and far scarier for administrators: they have less control over progress, less sight of it, (therefore) less to do, and a harder job justifying the rent they extract (in a government, this is called a “tax”; in a corporation, it is executive compensation) for providing their “vital” administration.

Once the desire for comprehensive urban planning is established, the logic of uniformity and regimentation is well nigh inexorable. Cost-effectiveness contributes to this tendency. Every concession to diversity is likely to entail an increase in time and budgetary cost.

Diversity

Another cost of this ideology is diversity in the things so regularised. That diversity and inclusion is the cause célèbre du jour, in the public and private sectors, sharpens the irony: since the typical approach to delivering diversity chimes with this desire for narratising legibility and high-modernism.

Diversity ought, you’d think, to be hard to pin down, its manifestations being naturally — well — diverse. It is the very benefit that accrues from the range of our differences and the interaction of our unique perspectives and lived experiences.

But, to get a handle it, organisations must make diversity legible. They do this by defining it in a limited and homogenous way. They gather data from their staff on that limited metric — to make it more legible, so that the organisation can propagate statistics about its “improving” diversity. Thus, “diversity” as the administration knows it is a formalised, homogenised, parameterised and regularised proxy of diversity, and no attention is paid to how this proxy diversity affects the behaviour of people in the organisation, for good or ill.

In any case, the point is clear: if imposed proxies can prompt the wealthy to restructure their tax affairs and French peasants to fill in their windows, so can it prompt those in a commercial organisation to behave in similarly counterproductive ways. There is an argument that whole segments of the infrastructure have developed for precisely that reason. Legal included.

An authoritarian state and prostrate civil society

Scott’s last two criteria are opposite sides of the same coin: an authoritarian state that can coerce the society it manages to bring its high modernist ideals to bear, and a subjugated population that cannot resist it.

Scott was writing in 1998, a few years after the collapse of communism, when Francis Fukuyama and others were declaring the end of history, the last man, all battles won and so forth, so was a little shoe-shuffly about this. He needn’t have been: not only have we seen the return of authoritarian governments and prostrate populations — the entire planet suffered eighteen months of solitary confinement without a great deal of complaint let us not forget — and the authoritarian disposition amongst the executive class and the supine one amongst the general population have always been a feature of the corporate sector.

Every “meaningful” aspect of your performance and your role is reduced to a data point: ID, location, salary, rank, position, performance, reporting line, holiday entitlement, sick leave, service catalog, performance objectives. All the work you do: the subtle analysis, the advocacy, the creative solutions, the informal network and ineffable judgments — all is, in the eyes of the executive, reduced to a grade, a rank and a number.

As for the high modernist ideal, well, this entire site is ironic homage to that, but orthodox “business strategy” presumes we can solve all conundrums in the landscape and then proceed sedately and without the need to be troubled by turbulent subject matter experts thereafter.

Metis

Talk of subject matter experts brings us nicely to Scott’s closing, where he introduces the concept, missing from the high modernist canon, of metis.

This is hard to describe — folk wisdom, knowhow, Odyssean cunning, experience — but in the corporate world it struck me as most resembling expertise. Ingenuity, problem-solving, lateral thinking; smarts for figuring out what to do on the fly if you are in a jam.

It is something that high modernists would abolish— their theory being that loose cannon employees making snap decisions is potentially catastrophic. Jams of this sort can and should be avoided by appropriate planning and the right algorithm: if you get the playbook right, subject matter experts aren’t needed.

Scott makes two interesting observations here. The first is that “metis” is much more efficient than an algorithm, even if you can find one to work. This is why (pace dear old Richard Dawkins) we catch flying baseballs not by solving differential equations in our heads, but by using the “gaze heuristic”.[2] You could — if you accept the reductionist stance — solve any problem with the right calculations, but the necessary data and processing power would be huge. Practical knowledge, on the other hand — metis — is “as economical and accurate as it needs to be, no more and no less, for addressing the problem at hand.”

This is the difference, says Scott, between Red Adair[3] and an articled clerk. There are some skills you cannot acquire except through experience: learning to sail, ride a bike, play a musical instrument or extinguish a civilisation-threatening oil well fire. You could spend as much time as you like with textbooks, but you will never master that kind of skill until you have done enough practical rehearsal.

This brings us to the last connection: complexity theory, systems analysis and normal accidents.

All of these come to the same conclusion: if you are dealing with tightly-coupled complex systems that interact in non-linear ways, no matter how much data you have or how sophisticated are your tools, mindless algorithms will not work. The only way to manage these risks is with experts on the ground, whom you empower to exercise judgment and make provisional decisions, which they can adjust as a situation unfolds. That is, with their metis.

If, in your high-modernist zeal, you have eliminated all those with metis from your operation, you may get by in times of peace and equity but, come the revolution, you are stuffed.

See also

References

  1. Charles Perrow’s Normal Accidents theory; systems theory as expounded by Donella H. Meadows, Thomas Kuhn’s The Structure of Scientific Revolutions
  2. Gerd Gigerenzer is fantastic on this.
  3. Younger readers may not remember Red Adair but in the Seventies, he was a proper Boys’ Own fire-fighting hero.