Anthropology of money: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit Advanced mobile edit
No edit summary
 
(17 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|banking|}}{{drop|I|magine an anthropological}} history of [[money]] that traces from outright arms-length [[barter]] to trade of goods against private promissory notes to the creation of bilateral indebtedness to the centralisation of promissory instruments through private intermediaries (i.e., banks) to the standardisation of promissory instruments against abstract units of value to the creation of currencies by central government agencies.
{{a|banking|}}{{drop|I| thought it}} might be interesting to contrive a mythical history of [[money]] from its status of non-existence to the present day. This might help understand what this mysterious thing called money is, how it works, where it came from, and where it might be going next.  


Not sure it really matters how historically accurate it is as long as it is plausible — each stage in the evolution must stand on its own two feet as a sustainable model of sociopolitical interaction — in biological terms, it must be a viable organism in the context of its given environment. But once we've done the exercise let’s map it against the record.
As you know, JC is a first-rate windbag but no kind of economist, much less an anthropologist, so this will not be an anatomically-correct social history of commerce or civilisation, but rather an exercise in imagining how money arose and why it has the unusual qualities it does.


Key waypoints in that transition:
It doesn’t matter that this story is not perfectly accurate — the details of how we got to where we are vary greatly depending on where you start from, after all — as long as every step is ''legally'' and ''economically'' plausible. 


====Zero trust====
One rule of evolution by natural selection is that each stage in an organism’s evolution must be viable in its own right: it must function and be fully fit for the environment in which it emerges. So it must be for the stages of the evolution of money. Each stage must be viable in its own right.  
{{Drop|A|ll exchanges for}} equivalent value, at arm’s length with no requirements for shared values, much less ongoing obligations between the parties (beyond letting each other retreat from the exchange place with their goods without violence) will necessary expectations of further trade.<ref>Game theory trade off works (is not a [[single round prisoners’ dilemma]]) because there is no possibility of defection: it is [[delivery versus payment]].</ref> This is “barter between aliens” more or less. It must be barter because any form promissory instrument or “currency” or abstract token of value implies consensus in a measurement or trust in the credit or performance of ''someone''.


Features: no reputational component bilateral, discrete, delivery versus payment, [[payment in kind]].
We will start with the outlying scenario that is disconnected from the rest: exchange of goods between “hostiles” where there is no community of trust or interest at all. This is [[barter]], and it gets economists and anthropologists quite worked up. 
 
From there we will look at the evolution of resource sharing ''within'' trusted communities, and how money arose out of that. As we will see, money only makes sense between communities with a significant degree of interdependence and shared interests and values.
 
A key theme we will return to is that money profoundly, inescapably, inevitably represents ''indebtedness''.
 
====Barter: zero trust====
{{Drop|A|ll exchanges for}} equivalent value, at arm’s length with no requirements for shared values, much less ongoing obligations between the parties (beyond letting each other retreat from the exchange place with their goods without violence) will necessary expectations of further trade.<ref>Game theory trade-off works (is not a [[single round prisoners’ dilemma]]) because there is no possibility of defection: it is [[delivery versus payment]].</ref> This is “barter between aliens”, more or less. It ''must'' be barter because any form of promissory instrument or “currency” or abstract token of value implies both consensus in measurement and trust in the credit or performance of the person providing the promise. A promise to pay, or do, something later is a form of indebtedness in the loosest sense. Pure play “barter” involves no indebtedness of any kind. To the extent that money is intrinsically an instrument of indebtedness, its origin does ''not'' — ''cannot'' — lie in [[barter]].
 
In any case, a barter arrangement is intrinsically unstable — it is only optimal in the absence of any common interest or language: the successful act of trading will soon create one, so we should not be surprised there is little in the anthropological record to suggest sustained “barter economies”. 
 
We mention barter here only to describe a viable means of transaction in that unmediated alien state where there is no trust or common interest.
====Simple community of interest====
====Simple community of interest====
{{drop|T|ransactions between persons}} known to each other in a community where there is an expectation or repeated trade and a memory of past trades, such that reputation is important. These premarket systems didn’t grow out of barter as such but were more in the nature of generalised reciprocal mutual contributions, relying on social memory. Participants “put in” and could “take out” according to their contribution. An important thing here is that these “social debts” were not exact, were not [[financialised]] and could never be exactly discharged. This was a key advantage: the residual unarticulated mutual indebtedness helped bind the community together. There was never a time where a participant could say “my debt is fully discharged; I owe you nothing”.<ref>[[David Graeber]] illustrates the point by reference to a modern family: the children would never repay their debts to their parents, and say, “therefore I owe you nothing and need never see you again.”</ref>  
{{drop|T|ransactions between persons}} within a community where they share interests, languages and have an expectation of repeat business and a memory of ''past'' business, is a very different proposition from hostile barter. Barter is annoying, and limited: it depends on a double coincidence of wants: I happen to want sheepskins, which you have, and you happen to want arrowheads, which I have. Much more useful is an arrangement where there is no such “double coincidence”: I want sheepskins, you don’t want my arrowheads, so we can somehow sort out what you need in return elsewhere in the community, or perhaps I will just ''promise'' to make it up to you later.  
 
These premarket systems didn’t grow out of [[barter]] but were more like generalised reciprocal mutual contributions, relying on social memory between in-groups. Here, participants “put in” and could “take out” according to their acknowledged contribution. These “social debts” were not exact: they could not be quantified — how do you directly compare arrowheads with sheepskins? What value is the loan of a tool? — and therefore were never exactly discharged. There was a residual ongoing mutual interdependence.
 
The nature of this mutual interdependence is ''indebtedness''. Not the [[financialised]], fully-accounted-for, monetarily fixed and time-bound indebtedness we are used to today, but “''social'' indebtedness”, whose point was not to be discharged, but to be ongoing. Community members would draw from the pool against an acknowledgement that they were bound to put something of broadly equivalent value back. It isn’t unitised in any way, ''yet'', but that is the underlying relationship. There is an early role for the “state”: pillars of the community like priests, elders and chiefs to enforce these community values.
 
The key advantage of this residual social indebtedness was its role in binding the community together. There was never a time where a participant could say “my debt to you is fully discharged; I owe you nothing”.<ref>[[David Graeber]] illustrates the point by reference to a modern family: the children would never repay their debts to their parents, and say, “therefore I owe you nothing and need never see you again.”</ref>  
 
If financial indebtedness is, in [[Finite and Infinite Games|James Carse]]’s terms, a “finite game” — time-bound and rule-bound and scheduled to definitively end at some point — then ''social'' indebtedness is an “''infinite'' game”: it has no rules, no timeframe and, it stretches out indefinitely into the future. The name of the game is to ''keep the arrangement going''. To ensure that, participants are incentivised to trust each other and act in good faith.
 
There was no need for encapsulated, barter-style “delivery versus payment” business. Rather, members of the community could contribute or withdraw from community resources “on account”, recorded in the general social memory. People talk: reputation was paramount. ''The community operated on credit''.


Features: fundamental reputational component, largely bilateral, accretive, delivery on account, [[payment in kind]], non-[[interest]] bearing, not [[financialised]].
Features: fundamental reputational component, largely bilateral, accretive, [[delivery on account]], [[payment in kind]], non-[[interest]] bearing, not [[financialised]].


====Units of account====
====Units of account====
{{drop|A|s communities grew}} more complex and multilateral it became harder to track mutual obligations. This involved (i) writing them down, and (ii) articulating their value against a community-recognised standard. The first of these were commodities: heads of cattle, volumes of grain as abstract articulations of value (not units of exchange as such). Precious metals emerged as convenient measures and, as they had no intrinsic utility, their value was less susceptible to supply shocks like crop failure. This sense of tabulation was the first step in the financialisation of indebtedness: now debts could be exactly quantified and discharged. No longer delivery versus payment, but delivery on account so reputation management still important. The social indebtedness was replaced by the long term benefits of cooperation ([[iterated prisoners’ dilemma]])
{{drop|A|s communities grew}} more complex and multilateral it became harder to keep track of these mutual obligations. The central pillars of the community began to write them down. This involved (i) writing them down, and (ii) articulating their value against a community-recognised standard. These would function as abstract articulations of value (not units of exchange).
 
Now we are taking that sense of abstract, ineffable community obligation and, literally, ''putting a number on it''. This we can add and subtract — but this is broadly a convenience to remove friction in transactions, to tamp down arguments, and speed the system up. People don't expect to fully and finally settle their debts, but it is helpful to centrally know what they are.
 
A number in the abstract would be weird — what is a “one” worth? — a number of ''somethings'', having an agreed stable value would work better.. But what?
 
Staple commodities were a good first choice for that community value system: everyone understands the “use” value of an ox or a barrel of grain — but their ''exchange'' values varied with supply and demand and could be dragged up or down as a result of weather events, crop failures, disease, war and so on. This made them less satisfactory as yardsticks of abstract value in the market.<ref> The [[metaphor]] is appropriate: a yardstick is a classic example of an abstract measurement not subject to supply and demand shocks!</ref>
 
====A stable store of value====
{{Drop|A|n ideal commodity}} “yardstick” would not fluctuate in this way. Its supply would be unusually stable — in that producing more of it would cost more than its prevailing exchange value — while on the demand side, it would not be depleted by consumption or wastage: it wouldn’t rust, rot, waste away or be eaten. It would be intrinsically ''precious'' — valuable in itself, just to be held.<ref> There is an interesting analogue here with [[intellectual property]] which, likewise, is not wasted or consumed when it is given away.</ref>
 
It would therefore hold a constant value, minimally exposed to supply or demand shocks. This would be a good measure of the exchange value of commodities that ''were'' vulnerable to supply and demand.
 
This is a pretty neat trick to pull off: a commodity in high demand but having no particular ''use''. What sort of magical compound is like this?
 
Gold, in a nutshell.
 
Gold and silver — the first “precious metals” — had no intrinsic utility, except as jewellery, and that was a kind of “non-destructive editing”  of the commodity that could reversed by melting it back into ingots.
 
Now the value of goods exchanged in the marketplace — and the credit and debt arrangements arising from their exchange — could be recorded by reference to a stable measure of value: a “notional”, or ''hypothetical'', quantity of gold or silver. No actual metal was involved in the exchange: it was simply an abstract measurement scale. Participants delivered or acquired commodities in the market against an update in the record, often maintained by a trusted central institution like a temple, of their nominal value in gold. This sense of tabulation was the first step in the [[financialisation]] of this community [[indebtedness]]: now one’s contributions and withdrawals from the community could be exactly quantified and memorialised.
 
====The centralised marketplace====
{{drop|A|s the centralised}} tabulation system caught on it enabled faster and more sophisticated transactions, brought more and more people into the market — which emerged as a physical meeting place in the town. Eventually, it became a victim of its own success: the central temple ledger struggled to effectively track and manage multilateral trading records between market participants who wished to transact with many different traders throughout the day.
 
Malleable metals were easy to unitise and convenient to carry in person and could embody the abstract unit of account in a portable, immediately verifiable form. To save recording transactions in a central ledger, merchants started to exchange actual weighed bits of metal directly in return for goods. This worked well and in their stash of coins, merchants could readily see how much credit they had at any time, but created certain problems and presented certain opportunities:
 
The key problems were the frictional costs of weighing and verifying metal purity and managing the potential for fraud through clipping coins and adulterating metal. At this stage, the metals were not symbolic of anything, but actual amounts of a commodity exchanged in discharge of a contract.
 
The key opportunities they could represent indebtedness and were easily tradable, which presented an opportunity for traders with a good supply of materials but, as yet, no metal to trade for goods and tools: they could borrow metal against the value of their material supplies.
 
====What about war====
{{Drop|T|he historically-minded}} among you will have clocked the peaceful, free-trading, libertardian model JC has drawn and will rightly be chafing against it. It was not all snowflakes and unicorns back in the day. There was [[problematic]] behaviour. Nor were inter-tribal relations based exclusively on a general agreement on tariffs and trade. For most of human history, and almost certainly for more of it as it unfurls, ''pace'' [[The End of History and the Last Man|Francis Fukuyama]] — communities spent a lot of time fighting, defending their territories from each others’ aggressions. This was hard to do in an uncoordinated way, and those societies that acquired a central “Leviathan” — whether by  outright domination, divine rights or the proceedings of an anarcho-syndicalist commune taking it in turns to act as sort of executive officer for the week — to take care of that business were better able to defend, and prosecute, the collective interest and keep the peace within it. If you could maintain a standing army you could keep folks straight in the market: and the state was soon involved in arbitrating disputes, standardising weights and measures, enforcing contacts and eventually minting coins with guaranteed weight and purity and penalising those who would debase or counterfeit the king’s currency. And the king had quite a bit of it, too: citizens contributed a portion of their personal capital and resources to the “crown” in return for its protection. The state became a significant owner of capital in its own right. The king’s currency became the standard. It acquired a symbolic value greater than its intrinsic value — precious metal didn't really have an intrinsic value remember — and we had a fully functioning fist currency.
 
====The cost of money====
{{Drop|W|ith a [[Money|currency]]}} we have created a new tradable quasi-commodity and this has implications for its return. Remember its role here: cash on hand represents valuable capital you have ''given away''. It denotes something owed to you that you do not have  it is an abstract ''receipt''.
 
Within the central ledger of the market, remember, a credit to your name of that stable representation of value — it was not yet a “store” of value; that only arrived later with metal coinage — represents an amount ''you do not have''. You got it in return for the productive capital you have given away. To be sure, it has value: it represents a ''potential'' capital investment in productive assets, but as long as you hold it in your purse and don’t spend it, it is capital unengaged and it earns no return. We should not be surprised that, over time, compared with productive capital, its relative value declines.
 
This challenges the idea of currency as a “stable store of ''value''”, but plainly the rate of wastage is unavoidable and predictable. Cash is a “wasting asset”.  You should not want to hold any more than you have to.
 
Happily, cash it is also a [[Transferable security|transferable]], [[Negotiable instrument|negotiable]] item: in the market, it trades like a commodity<ref>Though it isn’t an asset so much as an [[anti-asset]]</ref>. So, if one trader has  an excess of cash it does not wish to invest, other traders may be prepared to ''buy'' that cash, against a return representing that predictable nominal capital investment, so they can use it.
 
Now, in a single currency market, “buying” cash in the [[spot market]] is nonsensical — why would you pay a dollar for a dollar? — so such a transaction must “settle” in the future: you give me the cash I want now, and I will pay you for it later, plus an uplift representing your capital return over that period. You could analyse this as a “forward sale”, since you have no legal claims over the cash once you have given it to me, and what I pay you for it is, theoretically, a discrete sum, but in common parlance we call that a ''loan'': I let you have cash for a time, you give it back, and you pay me some “interest”.
 
For the loan to make sense, the interest should (i) broadly offset the wastage of the cash asset throughout the loan (ii) act as an “insurance premium” against the remote risk you cannot pay back the cash at maturity and (iii) give me a little extra for my trouble.
 
There was an alternative business of taking money from people with an excess, so you could lend it to people who needed it. The economics here were the same, only the little extra in (iii) was a negative sum from the proposed interest rate.
 
A class of market participants arose who were dedicated to sourcing “deposits” from those who had an excess, and aggregating and lending them to those who had too few. These businesses we know as banks.
 
====Capital====
We can also see that any capital that is disengaged from the market is a drag on productivity. Over a time period there will be a portion of currency sitting unused in this way.
 
In the “unit of account” phase there was a lot of this kind of wasteage. With the arrival of transferable currency this reduced, but merchats would still hold coin in their wallets (and not in a bank). With electronic banking, we carry less and less hard currency, and (in theory) our economy becomes more efficient.
 
 
 
 
 
The community trust built from rolling undischarged social indebtedness in the community was replaced by the long-term benefits of a reputation for cooperation ([[iterated prisoners’ dilemma]]). Those known and trusted to honour their commitments were more likely to gain access to further goods “on account” in bilateral arrangements.




Line 24: Line 103:
As such we can explain most bank activities as optimising the funding of their lending activities. Capital is stationary if held in cash — this is like being indebted to yourself, so you slowly lose value because your capital is not engaged — moves slowly if deployed against simple interest bearing instruments (or non interest bearing ones like trade receivables) and mines best if converted into cash and reinvested.
As such we can explain most bank activities as optimising the funding of their lending activities. Capital is stationary if held in cash — this is like being indebted to yourself, so you slowly lose value because your capital is not engaged — moves slowly if deployed against simple interest bearing instruments (or non interest bearing ones like trade receivables) and mines best if converted into cash and reinvested.


Twa thoughts: first, the drag of physical cash is not really a problem of malign central/reserve banking creating inflation by printing money, but more a function of its disengagement from the productive economy (physical cash is an “anti asset”).  
Two thoughts: first, the drag of physical cash is not really a problem of malign central/reserve banking creating inflation by printing money, but more a function of its disengagement from the productive economy (physical cash is an “anti asset”).  


Second, the cryptocurrency maximalist view that you can therefore take capital out of the “capitalist strip-mine” in the form of bitcoin and not suffer this loss of value is mistaken.
Second, the cryptocurrency maximalist view that you can therefore take capital out of the “capitalist strip-mine” in the form of bitcoin and not suffer this loss of value is mistaken.
{{small|80}}
{| class="wikitable"
|+ Caption text
|-
! Trade type !! Trust level !! Laterality !! Final settlement !! Indebtedness !! Interest !! Accounting !! Game style
|-
| Barter || Zero || Bilateral || On exchange || None || N/A || N/A || Finite
|-
| Community of interest|| High || Multilateral || None || Social || N/A|| N/A || Infinite
|-
| Units of account || High|| Multilateral|| On account || Social ||None || Centralised || Infinite
|-
| Stable store of value || Medium|| Multilateral|| Medium || On account || Financial || Centralised || Infinite
|-
| Coinage || Bilateral || Medium || On exchange || None || None || Decentralised || Finite
|}
</div>
{{ref}}

Latest revision as of 18:21, 4 December 2024

Banking basics
A recap of a few things you’d think financial professionals ought to know
Index: Click to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

I thought it might be interesting to contrive a mythical history of money from its status of non-existence to the present day. This might help understand what this mysterious thing called money is, how it works, where it came from, and where it might be going next.

As you know, JC is a first-rate windbag but no kind of economist, much less an anthropologist, so this will not be an anatomically-correct social history of commerce or civilisation, but rather an exercise in imagining how money arose and why it has the unusual qualities it does.

It doesn’t matter that this story is not perfectly accurate — the details of how we got to where we are vary greatly depending on where you start from, after all — as long as every step is legally and economically plausible.

One rule of evolution by natural selection is that each stage in an organism’s evolution must be viable in its own right: it must function and be fully fit for the environment in which it emerges. So it must be for the stages of the evolution of money. Each stage must be viable in its own right.

We will start with the outlying scenario that is disconnected from the rest: exchange of goods between “hostiles” where there is no community of trust or interest at all. This is barter, and it gets economists and anthropologists quite worked up.

From there we will look at the evolution of resource sharing within trusted communities, and how money arose out of that. As we will see, money only makes sense between communities with a significant degree of interdependence and shared interests and values.

A key theme we will return to is that money profoundly, inescapably, inevitably represents indebtedness.

Barter: zero trust

All exchanges for equivalent value, at arm’s length with no requirements for shared values, much less ongoing obligations between the parties (beyond letting each other retreat from the exchange place with their goods without violence) will necessary expectations of further trade.[1] This is “barter between aliens”, more or less. It must be barter because any form of promissory instrument or “currency” or abstract token of value implies both consensus in measurement and trust in the credit or performance of the person providing the promise. A promise to pay, or do, something later is a form of indebtedness in the loosest sense. Pure play “barter” involves no indebtedness of any kind. To the extent that money is intrinsically an instrument of indebtedness, its origin does notcannot — lie in barter.

In any case, a barter arrangement is intrinsically unstable — it is only optimal in the absence of any common interest or language: the successful act of trading will soon create one, so we should not be surprised there is little in the anthropological record to suggest sustained “barter economies”.

We mention barter here only to describe a viable means of transaction in that unmediated alien state where there is no trust or common interest.

Simple community of interest

Transactions between persons within a community where they share interests, languages and have an expectation of repeat business and a memory of past business, is a very different proposition from hostile barter. Barter is annoying, and limited: it depends on a double coincidence of wants: I happen to want sheepskins, which you have, and you happen to want arrowheads, which I have. Much more useful is an arrangement where there is no such “double coincidence”: I want sheepskins, you don’t want my arrowheads, so we can somehow sort out what you need in return elsewhere in the community, or perhaps I will just promise to make it up to you later.

These premarket systems didn’t grow out of barter but were more like generalised reciprocal mutual contributions, relying on social memory between in-groups. Here, participants “put in” and could “take out” according to their acknowledged contribution. These “social debts” were not exact: they could not be quantified — how do you directly compare arrowheads with sheepskins? What value is the loan of a tool? — and therefore were never exactly discharged. There was a residual ongoing mutual interdependence.

The nature of this mutual interdependence is indebtedness. Not the financialised, fully-accounted-for, monetarily fixed and time-bound indebtedness we are used to today, but “social indebtedness”, whose point was not to be discharged, but to be ongoing. Community members would draw from the pool against an acknowledgement that they were bound to put something of broadly equivalent value back. It isn’t unitised in any way, yet, but that is the underlying relationship. There is an early role for the “state”: pillars of the community like priests, elders and chiefs to enforce these community values.

The key advantage of this residual social indebtedness was its role in binding the community together. There was never a time where a participant could say “my debt to you is fully discharged; I owe you nothing”.[2]

If financial indebtedness is, in James Carse’s terms, a “finite game” — time-bound and rule-bound and scheduled to definitively end at some point — then social indebtedness is an “infinite game”: it has no rules, no timeframe and, it stretches out indefinitely into the future. The name of the game is to keep the arrangement going. To ensure that, participants are incentivised to trust each other and act in good faith.

There was no need for encapsulated, barter-style “delivery versus payment” business. Rather, members of the community could contribute or withdraw from community resources “on account”, recorded in the general social memory. People talk: reputation was paramount. The community operated on credit.

Features: fundamental reputational component, largely bilateral, accretive, delivery on account, payment in kind, non-interest bearing, not financialised.

Units of account

As communities grew more complex and multilateral it became harder to keep track of these mutual obligations. The central pillars of the community began to write them down. This involved (i) writing them down, and (ii) articulating their value against a community-recognised standard. These would function as abstract articulations of value (not units of exchange).

Now we are taking that sense of abstract, ineffable community obligation and, literally, putting a number on it. This we can add and subtract — but this is broadly a convenience to remove friction in transactions, to tamp down arguments, and speed the system up. People don't expect to fully and finally settle their debts, but it is helpful to centrally know what they are.

A number in the abstract would be weird — what is a “one” worth? — a number of somethings, having an agreed stable value would work better.. But what?

Staple commodities were a good first choice for that community value system: everyone understands the “use” value of an ox or a barrel of grain — but their exchange values varied with supply and demand and could be dragged up or down as a result of weather events, crop failures, disease, war and so on. This made them less satisfactory as yardsticks of abstract value in the market.[3]

A stable store of value

An ideal commodity “yardstick” would not fluctuate in this way. Its supply would be unusually stable — in that producing more of it would cost more than its prevailing exchange value — while on the demand side, it would not be depleted by consumption or wastage: it wouldn’t rust, rot, waste away or be eaten. It would be intrinsically precious — valuable in itself, just to be held.[4]

It would therefore hold a constant value, minimally exposed to supply or demand shocks. This would be a good measure of the exchange value of commodities that were vulnerable to supply and demand.

This is a pretty neat trick to pull off: a commodity in high demand but having no particular use. What sort of magical compound is like this?

Gold, in a nutshell.

Gold and silver — the first “precious metals” — had no intrinsic utility, except as jewellery, and that was a kind of “non-destructive editing” of the commodity that could reversed by melting it back into ingots.

Now the value of goods exchanged in the marketplace — and the credit and debt arrangements arising from their exchange — could be recorded by reference to a stable measure of value: a “notional”, or hypothetical, quantity of gold or silver. No actual metal was involved in the exchange: it was simply an abstract measurement scale. Participants delivered or acquired commodities in the market against an update in the record, often maintained by a trusted central institution like a temple, of their nominal value in gold. This sense of tabulation was the first step in the financialisation of this community indebtedness: now one’s contributions and withdrawals from the community could be exactly quantified and memorialised.

The centralised marketplace

As the centralised tabulation system caught on it enabled faster and more sophisticated transactions, brought more and more people into the market — which emerged as a physical meeting place in the town. Eventually, it became a victim of its own success: the central temple ledger struggled to effectively track and manage multilateral trading records between market participants who wished to transact with many different traders throughout the day.

Malleable metals were easy to unitise and convenient to carry in person and could embody the abstract unit of account in a portable, immediately verifiable form. To save recording transactions in a central ledger, merchants started to exchange actual weighed bits of metal directly in return for goods. This worked well and in their stash of coins, merchants could readily see how much credit they had at any time, but created certain problems and presented certain opportunities:

The key problems were the frictional costs of weighing and verifying metal purity and managing the potential for fraud through clipping coins and adulterating metal. At this stage, the metals were not symbolic of anything, but actual amounts of a commodity exchanged in discharge of a contract.

The key opportunities they could represent indebtedness and were easily tradable, which presented an opportunity for traders with a good supply of materials but, as yet, no metal to trade for goods and tools: they could borrow metal against the value of their material supplies.

What about war

The historically-minded among you will have clocked the peaceful, free-trading, libertardian model JC has drawn and will rightly be chafing against it. It was not all snowflakes and unicorns back in the day. There was problematic behaviour. Nor were inter-tribal relations based exclusively on a general agreement on tariffs and trade. For most of human history, and almost certainly for more of it as it unfurls, pace Francis Fukuyama — communities spent a lot of time fighting, defending their territories from each others’ aggressions. This was hard to do in an uncoordinated way, and those societies that acquired a central “Leviathan” — whether by outright domination, divine rights or the proceedings of an anarcho-syndicalist commune taking it in turns to act as sort of executive officer for the week — to take care of that business were better able to defend, and prosecute, the collective interest and keep the peace within it. If you could maintain a standing army you could keep folks straight in the market: and the state was soon involved in arbitrating disputes, standardising weights and measures, enforcing contacts and eventually minting coins with guaranteed weight and purity and penalising those who would debase or counterfeit the king’s currency. And the king had quite a bit of it, too: citizens contributed a portion of their personal capital and resources to the “crown” in return for its protection. The state became a significant owner of capital in its own right. The king’s currency became the standard. It acquired a symbolic value greater than its intrinsic value — precious metal didn't really have an intrinsic value remember — and we had a fully functioning fist currency.

The cost of money

With a currency we have created a new tradable quasi-commodity and this has implications for its return. Remember its role here: cash on hand represents valuable capital you have given away. It denotes something owed to you that you do not have it is an abstract receipt.

Within the central ledger of the market, remember, a credit to your name of that stable representation of value — it was not yet a “store” of value; that only arrived later with metal coinage — represents an amount you do not have. You got it in return for the productive capital you have given away. To be sure, it has value: it represents a potential capital investment in productive assets, but as long as you hold it in your purse and don’t spend it, it is capital unengaged and it earns no return. We should not be surprised that, over time, compared with productive capital, its relative value declines.

This challenges the idea of currency as a “stable store of value”, but plainly the rate of wastage is unavoidable and predictable. Cash is a “wasting asset”. You should not want to hold any more than you have to.

Happily, cash it is also a transferable, negotiable item: in the market, it trades like a commodity[5]. So, if one trader has an excess of cash it does not wish to invest, other traders may be prepared to buy that cash, against a return representing that predictable nominal capital investment, so they can use it.

Now, in a single currency market, “buying” cash in the spot market is nonsensical — why would you pay a dollar for a dollar? — so such a transaction must “settle” in the future: you give me the cash I want now, and I will pay you for it later, plus an uplift representing your capital return over that period. You could analyse this as a “forward sale”, since you have no legal claims over the cash once you have given it to me, and what I pay you for it is, theoretically, a discrete sum, but in common parlance we call that a loan: I let you have cash for a time, you give it back, and you pay me some “interest”.

For the loan to make sense, the interest should (i) broadly offset the wastage of the cash asset throughout the loan (ii) act as an “insurance premium” against the remote risk you cannot pay back the cash at maturity and (iii) give me a little extra for my trouble.

There was an alternative business of taking money from people with an excess, so you could lend it to people who needed it. The economics here were the same, only the little extra in (iii) was a negative sum from the proposed interest rate.

A class of market participants arose who were dedicated to sourcing “deposits” from those who had an excess, and aggregating and lending them to those who had too few. These businesses we know as banks.

Capital

We can also see that any capital that is disengaged from the market is a drag on productivity. Over a time period there will be a portion of currency sitting unused in this way.

In the “unit of account” phase there was a lot of this kind of wasteage. With the arrival of transferable currency this reduced, but merchats would still hold coin in their wallets (and not in a bank). With electronic banking, we carry less and less hard currency, and (in theory) our economy becomes more efficient.



The community trust built from rolling undischarged social indebtedness in the community was replaced by the long-term benefits of a reputation for cooperation (iterated prisoners’ dilemma). Those known and trusted to honour their commitments were more likely to gain access to further goods “on account” in bilateral arrangements.


The physical marketplace where traders of all goods gathered in a single location formative of early forms of transferrable credit. It strikes me that the need to “monetise” abstract receivables of manufactured goods to acquire more materials to manufacture more goods for sale is a key driver of an economy in its early stages.

Even today the velocity at which we can recycle receivables (or promissory instruments not only reduces our reliance on (and cost of) debt funding, but maximises the return of our receivable assets by converting them into cash that can be invested in productive capital.

As such we can explain most bank activities as optimising the funding of their lending activities. Capital is stationary if held in cash — this is like being indebted to yourself, so you slowly lose value because your capital is not engaged — moves slowly if deployed against simple interest bearing instruments (or non interest bearing ones like trade receivables) and mines best if converted into cash and reinvested.

Two thoughts: first, the drag of physical cash is not really a problem of malign central/reserve banking creating inflation by printing money, but more a function of its disengagement from the productive economy (physical cash is an “anti asset”).

Second, the cryptocurrency maximalist view that you can therefore take capital out of the “capitalist strip-mine” in the form of bitcoin and not suffer this loss of value is mistaken.

Caption text
Trade type Trust level Laterality Final settlement Indebtedness Interest Accounting Game style
Barter Zero Bilateral On exchange None N/A N/A Finite
Community of interest High Multilateral None Social N/A N/A Infinite
Units of account High Multilateral On account Social None Centralised Infinite
Stable store of value Medium Multilateral Medium On account Financial Centralised Infinite
Coinage Bilateral Medium On exchange None None Decentralised Finite

References

  1. Game theory trade-off works (is not a single round prisoners’ dilemma) because there is no possibility of defection: it is delivery versus payment.
  2. David Graeber illustrates the point by reference to a modern family: the children would never repay their debts to their parents, and say, “therefore I owe you nothing and need never see you again.”
  3. The metaphor is appropriate: a yardstick is a classic example of an abstract measurement not subject to supply and demand shocks!
  4. There is an interesting analogue here with intellectual property which, likewise, is not wasted or consumed when it is given away.
  5. Though it isn’t an asset so much as an anti-asset