Gizmo pelmanism: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|devil|}}{{quote|<small>“The little dongly things I am concerned with (and they are by no means the only species of little dongly things with which the micro-electronics world is infested) are the external power adaptors which laptops and palmtops and external drives and cassette recorders and telephone answering machines and powered speakers and other incredibly necessary gizmos need to step down the mains AC supply from either 120 volts or 240 volts to 6 volts DC. Or 4.5 volts DC. Or 9 volts DC. Or 12 volts DC. At 500 milliamps. Or 300 milliamps. Or 1200 milliamps. They have positive tips and negative sleeves on their plugs, unless they are the type that has negative tips and positive sleeves. By the time you multiply all these different variables together you end up with a fairly major industry which exists, so far as I can tell, to fill my cupboards with little dongly things none of which I can ever positively identify without playing gizmo pelmanism. The usual method of finding a little dongly thing that actually matches a gizmo I want to use is to go and buy another one, at a price that can physically drive the air from your body.
{{a|devil|}}{{quote|<small>“The little dongly things I am concerned with are the external power adaptors which laptops, palmtops, cassette recorders<ref>Adams died a while a go now, may he rest in peace.</ref> and other incredibly necessary gizmos need to step down the mains AC supply from either 120v or 240v to 6v DC. Or 4.5v DC. Or 9v DC. Or 12v DC. At 500 mA. Or 300 mA. Or 1200 mA. They have positive tips and negative sleeves on their plugs, unless they have negative tips and positive sleeves.


Now why is this? Well, there’s one possible theory, which is that just as Xerox is really in the business of selling toner cartridges, Sony is really in the little dongly power-supply business.
By the time you multiply all these together you end up with a major industry which exists, so far as I can tell, to fill my cupboards with little dongly things none of which I can ever positively identify without playing [[gizmo pelmanism]].
 
Now why is this? Well, there’s one theory, which is that just as Xerox is really in the business of selling toner cartridges, Sony is really in the little dongly power-supply business.


Another possible reason is that it is sheer blinding idiocy. It couldn’t possibly be that could it?”</small>
Another possible reason is that it is sheer blinding idiocy. It couldn’t possibly be that could it?”</small>
:— Douglas Adams}}
:— Douglas Adams}}


In the same vein as Douglas Adams, {{author|W. Edwards Deming}} writes<ref>{{br|The Essential Deming}}, ed. Joyce Orsini, Ch. 7.</ref> coherently about the value ''to the whole system'' of commoditised public standards: railway gauges; fork-lift pallets, containers — which between them just make the world’s life easier. No single solution is perfect — undoubtedly some advantages accrue to having wide gauges, and some to having narrow gauges, but ''neither confers as much net benefit as having everyone on the same gauge''.
“[[Gizmo pelmanism]]” is such a beautiful concept. It could describe much of modern legal practice.
 
In much the same vein, {{author|W. Edwards Deming}} writes<ref>{{br|The Essential Deming}}, ed. Joyce Orsini, Ch. 7.</ref> about the value ''to the whole system'' of commoditised public standards: railway gauges; fork-lift pallets, containers — standards which, once everyone adopts them, just make the whole world’s life easier. No single solution is perfect — undoubtedly some advantages accrue to having wide gauges, and some to having narrow gauges, but ''neither confers as much net benefit as having everyone on the same gauge''. Once there is critical mass, the incentives point only one way.
 
But how to achieve critical mass? One way is regulation: it might aggravate laissez-faire purists, who would say regulation shouldn’t be necessary, but it does work. The dear old [[European Union]] — remember when the UK was in the EU? Fun times — has been a standard bearer: their public common standard for phone chargers in 2009.<ref>[https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/MEMO_09_301 press release here].</ref> This change, whcih came ''cover strong objections from Apple''<ref>[https://appleinsider.com/articles/20/02/02/what-the-eu-mandate-for-a-common-smartphone-charger-means What the EU mandate for a common smartphone charger means] — ''Apple Insider]]</ref> boosted the move towards the USB-C standard. Suddenly, up to a given wattage, you can plug any device in anywhere, and it works. Apple seems to have survived and, I dare say, thrived notwithstanding.
 
The [[JC]] humbly submits, with the same unmediated gut instinct that propels many of his strongest convictions, that those who try to build ''proprietary'' interfaces out of touch-points that should be ''common'' — nodes, intersection points on a distributed network, utility crossings where everyone (bar a gate-keeping [[rent-seeker]]) would benefit from transit without friction — deserve a place in the stockade where we can all pelt them with cabbage.
 
To be sure, ''trying'' to impose a toll gate can be a self-imposed stockade anyway (remember Betamax?) — but not always: for {{strike|Apple|vendors who dominate their markets}}, proprietary formats survive, even those which wilfully interpose friction (DVD region encoding!) and thrive. At ''all'' of our costs. ''Even the dominant vendors’''.
 
But shouldn’t the unmediated forces of competition work so that common standards emerge by themselves? If not, ''why not''? What incentives are at play that prevent it?


Even the dear old [[European Union]] — remember when the UK was in the EU? Fun times — was un-idiotic enough to regulate a public common standard for phone chargers in 2009<ref>[https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/MEMO_09_301 press release here].</ref> So was born the USB standard: amazing: up to a given wattage, you can plug any device in anywhere, and it works.
Where commerce has worked this way, helped by the enlightened unselfishness of people like Tim Berners-Lee<ref>The World Wide Internet.</ref> and Jimmy Wales<ref>WikiMedia.</ref> ''staggering'' things have come about. Where it has not — and we are bound to note legal practice as being such a place — everyone remains mired in complication, chaos, cost, delay and, above all, ''[[tedium]]''. Imagine if a contract were a universal API for all commerce. This is what it should be: a contract ''is'' a transfer: it is a connection point between two nodes on a network. Why are we so far from the [[end-to-end principle]]?


The [[JC]] humbly submits, with the same unmediated gut instinct that propels many of his strongest convictions, that those who try to build ''proprietary'' interfaces out of touchpoints that should be ''common'' — nodes, intersection points on a distributed network, utility crossings where everyone (bar a gate-keeping [[rent-seeker]]) would benefit from transit without friction — deserve a special place in in a stockade where they can be pelted with cabbage.  
You can put this down in good part to [[Antitrust|anticompetitive]] instincts: regulatory and [[Paradigm|sociological]] barriers to entry to the legal profession — the Law Society’s and the Bar Association’s very ''raison d’etre'' is to maintain the stance that legal practice is ineffable. [[ISDA]] claims intellectual property in what should be — surely ''is'' — a common public utility.


To be sure, trying to impose a toll gate, can be like putting yourself in a stockade anyway (remember Betamax?) — but enough such proprietary formats survive, even those which wilfully interpose friction (DVD region encoding!) to make us ask how it ever come to that? Shouldn’t the unmediated forces of competition work so that common standards emerge by themselves? If not, ''why not''? What incentives are at play that prevent it?
This is our challenge: to overcome our ingrained instinct to regard the quotidian tools of our trade assomehow [[Secret sauce|special]]. For we do not add value complicating [[boilerplate]].


Where commerce has worked this way, through the enlightened altruism of people like Tim Berners-Lee<ref>The World Wide Internet.</ref> and Jimmy Wales<ref>WikiMedia.</ref> staggering things have come about. Where it has not — and we are bound to note legal practice as being such a place — we remain mired in complication, chaos, cost, delay and, above all, ''tedium''. A contract ''is'' a transfer: it is a connection point between two nodes on a network. Why are we so far from the [[end-to-end principle]]?
Set your loved ones free, [[legal eagle]]s: contributing to a common fund allows the wisdom of the crowd to winnow down and fitness-select the best terms for everyone: ''stop claiming false propriety over common public standards.  


It seems to me that anticompetitive forces: instincts to corner markets, claim false propriety in what should be standards, and —ironically enough — the disincentives for competitors to collaborate that are created by [[antitrust]] regulation. Each of these forces merchants and specialists to retreat into their corners; to rent-seek; to claim [[secret sauce]] in something that is really nothing of the kind.
No more [[gizmo pelmanism]]


{{sa}}
{{sa}}

Revision as of 18:15, 26 February 2021

In which the curmudgeonly old sod puts the world to rights.
Index — Click ᐅ to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

“The little dongly things I am concerned with are the external power adaptors which laptops, palmtops, cassette recorders[1] and other incredibly necessary gizmos need to step down the mains AC supply from either 120v or 240v to 6v DC. Or 4.5v DC. Or 9v DC. Or 12v DC. At 500 mA. Or 300 mA. Or 1200 mA. They have positive tips and negative sleeves on their plugs, unless they have negative tips and positive sleeves.

By the time you multiply all these together you end up with a major industry which exists, so far as I can tell, to fill my cupboards with little dongly things none of which I can ever positively identify without playing gizmo pelmanism.

Now why is this? Well, there’s one theory, which is that just as Xerox is really in the business of selling toner cartridges, Sony is really in the little dongly power-supply business.

Another possible reason is that it is sheer blinding idiocy. It couldn’t possibly be that could it?”

— Douglas Adams

Gizmo pelmanism” is such a beautiful concept. It could describe much of modern legal practice.

In much the same vein, W. Edwards Deming writes[2] about the value to the whole system of commoditised public standards: railway gauges; fork-lift pallets, containers — standards which, once everyone adopts them, just make the whole world’s life easier. No single solution is perfect — undoubtedly some advantages accrue to having wide gauges, and some to having narrow gauges, but neither confers as much net benefit as having everyone on the same gauge. Once there is critical mass, the incentives point only one way.

But how to achieve critical mass? One way is regulation: it might aggravate laissez-faire purists, who would say regulation shouldn’t be necessary, but it does work. The dear old European Union — remember when the UK was in the EU? Fun times — has been a standard bearer: their public common standard for phone chargers in 2009.[3] This change, whcih came cover strong objections from Apple[4] boosted the move towards the USB-C standard. Suddenly, up to a given wattage, you can plug any device in anywhere, and it works. Apple seems to have survived and, I dare say, thrived notwithstanding.

The JC humbly submits, with the same unmediated gut instinct that propels many of his strongest convictions, that those who try to build proprietary interfaces out of touch-points that should be common — nodes, intersection points on a distributed network, utility crossings where everyone (bar a gate-keeping rent-seeker) would benefit from transit without friction — deserve a place in the stockade where we can all pelt them with cabbage.

To be sure, trying to impose a toll gate can be a self-imposed stockade anyway (remember Betamax?) — but not always: for Apple vendors who dominate their markets, proprietary formats survive, even those which wilfully interpose friction (DVD region encoding!) and thrive. At all of our costs. Even the dominant vendors’.

But shouldn’t the unmediated forces of competition work so that common standards emerge by themselves? If not, why not? What incentives are at play that prevent it?

Where commerce has worked this way, helped by the enlightened unselfishness of people like Tim Berners-Lee[5] and Jimmy Wales[6] staggering things have come about. Where it has not — and we are bound to note legal practice as being such a place — everyone remains mired in complication, chaos, cost, delay and, above all, tedium. Imagine if a contract were a universal API for all commerce. This is what it should be: a contract is a transfer: it is a connection point between two nodes on a network. Why are we so far from the end-to-end principle?

You can put this down in good part to anticompetitive instincts: regulatory and sociological barriers to entry to the legal profession — the Law Society’s and the Bar Association’s very raison d’etre is to maintain the stance that legal practice is ineffable. ISDA claims intellectual property in what should be — surely is — a common public utility.

This is our challenge: to overcome our ingrained instinct to regard the quotidian tools of our trade assomehow special. For we do not add value complicating boilerplate.

Set your loved ones free, legal eagles: contributing to a common fund allows the wisdom of the crowd to winnow down and fitness-select the best terms for everyone: stop claiming false propriety over common public standards.

No more gizmo pelmanism

See also

References

  1. Adams died a while a go now, may he rest in peace.
  2. The Essential Deming, ed. Joyce Orsini, Ch. 7.
  3. press release here.
  4. What the EU mandate for a common smartphone charger meansApple Insider]]
  5. The World Wide Internet.
  6. WikiMedia.