Extreme prejudice: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Created page with "===Replacement premium=== {{A|hr|}}Now you might be inclined to look at this and think, well, this is a fine state of affairs. By pruning the truly dismal and letting jump..."
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
 
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Line 1: Line 1:
{{A|hr|}}
===Replacement premium===
===Replacement premium===
{{A|hr|}}Now you might be [[inclined]] to look at this and think, well, this is a fine state of affairs. By pruning the truly dismal and letting jumped-up and flighty go, we are nicely containing our costs within a tight range. This is depends on your not needing to replace them.
Now you might be [[inclined]] to look at this and think, “well, this is a fine state of affairs: by pruning the truly dismal in periodic job lots and letting the jumped-up and flighty go, we are nicely containing our costs within a tight range.


Indeed, in an organisation big enough to have a [[human resources]] department you probably don’t — or at least ''wouldn’t'', if you could hang on to staff who were any good and get rid of the grifters. [[Parkinson’s law]] obtains.  
This does depend on you not needing to replace employees who leave. The operating theory — honoured in the breach — is that [[RIF]] candidates are indeed surplus to requirements. [[Lateral quitter]]s less so but, in an organisation big enough to have its own [[human resources]] department,<ref>We have a theory that the point at which a firm acquires it's own a dedicated [[HR]] function is the tipping point at which it  begins its sure descent into sclerotic middle age.</ref> you probably don’t need to replace leavers — or at least ''wouldn’t'', if you could hang on to those staff who actually get things done, while getting rid of grifters. [[Parkinson’s law]] obtains.  All big organisations have more middle management staff than they need.


But if all you have left are the plodders, do not expect them to take up the slack. You will need a replacement, and — unlike the person who just departed — you must per her her actual value. At this point you have categorically worsened your position.
“Middle management” is a contradiction in terms, after all.
 
But it is a canny organisation that only loses its grifters. if all you have left are work-shy plodders, do not expect them to take up the slack. You will need to back-fill departees, and — unlike those departing — you must pay the going rate.  
 
At this point you have categorically ''worsened'' your position.


===Quid pro quo===
===Quid pro quo===
The good burghers of HR are no more inquisitive about the ''underperformers''. They should be. Generally, clods are allowed to lie fallow, unfeasibly long periods, languishing in a pool of non-advancement, continuing to draw a poor salary still more than they are worth — until finally tilled at one of the firm’s irregular mass [[RIF|culls]]. Here many laggards and no small number of good ’uns, are dispensed with at once, more or less indiscriminately.
The good burghers of [[HR]] are scarcely more inquisitive about ''underperformers'' than they are about [[lateral quitter]]s. They should be.  
 
Generally, clods are allowed to lie fallow for unfeasibly long periods, languishing in a pool of non-advancement, continuing to draw a underwhelming salaries in that they are more than they are worth — until finally tilled at one of the firm’s irregular mass [[RIF|culls]]. Here many laggards and no small number of good ’uns, are dispensed with at once, more or less indiscriminately.
 
[[Redundancy round]]s are a lazy, cowardly way of getting rid of staff you should have actively managed out. [[RIF]]s let you dress up performance management as ”resource reallocation” — something it really isn’t. These are staff requiring,and deserving, termination with extreme prejudice who can hang on thanks to well-meant but doltish workplace legislation.
 
Professional services firms are “[[QIB]]”s of the employment world  they are experienced, educated, they have easy access to professional advice and are perfectly capable of assessing and for an extended time bearing the risks of bad performance.
 
They are not sweatshop workers. They are neither treated, nor paid, like itinerant fruit pickers. They don't need the protection of unions and benign but patronising employment conditions.  The usual labour protection rules should not apply.
 
This would be for everyone's good — except the grifters and shitty employers.
 
We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have the right idea: ''employment at will''. Well-meant formalistic barriers to removing staff  have the unintended consequence of increasing barriers to ''hiring'' staff, since it is that much harder to reverse a duff hiring decision.


[[Redundancy round]]s are a lazy, cowardly way of getting rid of staff you should have actively managed up or out. RIFs let you dress up performance management as ”resource reallocation” — something it really isn’t.
It is mad really: finance professionals are not pit-workers. They have market power and a liberal education: they don’t need the unionised protections. ''Good'' staff shouldn’t want them. ''Bad'' staff shouldn’t be entitled to them.  


We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have the right idea: employment at will. Well-meant formalistic barriers to removing staff  have the unintended consequence of increasing barriers to ''hiring'' staff, since it is that much harder to reverse a duff hiring decision.
Good staff erect personal defences against mistreatment termination as they go: their contributions, their expertise, their institutional knowledge and their rich, informal networks name then to good to mistreat. But, irony: if workplace regulation makes it harder to hire, this gives shitty employers licence to treat good staff worse, as they have fewer options to leave.


It is mad really: finance professionals are not pit-workers. They have market power and a liberal education: they don’t need the unionised protections. Good staff shouldn’t want them. Good staff erect their own personal defences against termination as they go: their contributions, their expertise, their institutional knowledge and their rich, informal networks.  
No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional [[diversity]]. Smart firms will ensure they have cultural and cognitive diversity because the universe of business is culturally diverse. Firms that don’t will go out of business. Q.E.D.


No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional diversity. Smart firms will ensure they have it. Firms that doing will go out of business. Q.E.D.
End of day, professional services employers should not have to be a privatised welfare system for their staff. The defence against [[mediocrity drift]] is to quickly deal with laggers.  


End of day, firms are not a welfare system for their employees. The defence against mediocrity drift is to quickly deal with laggers. The first tool here is discretionary bonus. With this you can bring down cost and push the laggard into the safe zone. If you are flatlining on doughnuts, and you can’t figure out a way of redeploying said laggard, then have the conversation. Be clear, have it early.
A byThe first tool here is discretionary bonus. With this you can bring down cost and push the laggard into the safe zone. If you are flatlining on doughnuts, and you can’t figure out a way of redeploying said laggard, then have the conversation. Be clear, have it early.
===Look after what you have===
===Look after what you have===
How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the ''good performers''.  
How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the ''good performers''.  

Revision as of 19:19, 5 December 2022

The Human Resources military-industrial complex
The instrument (the “telescreen”, it was called) could be dimmed, but there was no way of shutting it off completely.
Index: Click to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.


Replacement premium

Now you might be inclined to look at this and think, “well, this is a fine state of affairs: by pruning the truly dismal in periodic job lots and letting the jumped-up and flighty go, we are nicely containing our costs within a tight range.”

This does depend on you not needing to replace employees who leave. The operating theory — honoured in the breach — is that RIF candidates are indeed surplus to requirements. Lateral quitters less so but, in an organisation big enough to have its own human resources department,[1] you probably don’t need to replace leavers — or at least wouldn’t, if you could hang on to those staff who actually get things done, while getting rid of grifters. Parkinson’s law obtains. All big organisations have more middle management staff than they need.

“Middle management” is a contradiction in terms, after all.

But it is a canny organisation that only loses its grifters. if all you have left are work-shy plodders, do not expect them to take up the slack. You will need to back-fill departees, and — unlike those departing — you must pay the going rate.

At this point you have categorically worsened your position.

Quid pro quo

The good burghers of HR are scarcely more inquisitive about underperformers than they are about lateral quitters. They should be.

Generally, clods are allowed to lie fallow for unfeasibly long periods, languishing in a pool of non-advancement, continuing to draw a underwhelming salaries — in that they are more than they are worth — until finally tilled at one of the firm’s irregular mass culls. Here many laggards and no small number of good ’uns, are dispensed with at once, more or less indiscriminately.

Redundancy rounds are a lazy, cowardly way of getting rid of staff you should have actively managed out. RIFs let you dress up performance management as ”resource reallocation” — something it really isn’t. These are staff requiring,and deserving, termination with extreme prejudice who can hang on thanks to well-meant but doltish workplace legislation.

Professional services firms are “QIB”s of the employment world they are experienced, educated, they have easy access to professional advice and are perfectly capable of assessing and for an extended time bearing the risks of bad performance.

They are not sweatshop workers. They are neither treated, nor paid, like itinerant fruit pickers. They don't need the protection of unions and benign but patronising employment conditions. The usual labour protection rules should not apply.

This would be for everyone's good — except the grifters and shitty employers.

We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have the right idea: employment at will. Well-meant formalistic barriers to removing staff have the unintended consequence of increasing barriers to hiring staff, since it is that much harder to reverse a duff hiring decision.

It is mad really: finance professionals are not pit-workers. They have market power and a liberal education: they don’t need the unionised protections. Good staff shouldn’t want them. Bad staff shouldn’t be entitled to them.

Good staff erect personal defences against mistreatment termination as they go: their contributions, their expertise, their institutional knowledge and their rich, informal networks name then to good to mistreat. But, irony: if workplace regulation makes it harder to hire, this gives shitty employers licence to treat good staff worse, as they have fewer options to leave.

No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional diversity. Smart firms will ensure they have cultural and cognitive diversity because the universe of business is culturally diverse. Firms that don’t will go out of business. Q.E.D.

End of day, professional services employers should not have to be a privatised welfare system for their staff. The defence against mediocrity drift is to quickly deal with laggers.

A byThe first tool here is discretionary bonus. With this you can bring down cost and push the laggard into the safe zone. If you are flatlining on doughnuts, and you can’t figure out a way of redeploying said laggard, then have the conversation. Be clear, have it early.

Look after what you have

How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the good performers.

Try to stop them leaving. Do this by figuring out why they are leaving. There may be complicated sociological explanations, but for most places it will take no towering intellectual insight to figure it out. In broad strokes it boils down to: money, progression, and quality of work.

Another way of looking at that continuum is this: you pay poor employees more than they are worth to you, and good employees, less than than they are worth, expect to have crappy employees.

  1. We have a theory that the point at which a firm acquires it's own a dedicated HR function is the tipping point at which it begins its sure descent into sclerotic middle age.