Synthetic prime brokerage and the risk of tax recharacterisation: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
(Created page with "{{a|pb|}} ===Why there is no real risk of a synthetic equity position being a secret custody position doing the taxman out of his money===")
 
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|pb|}}
{{a|pb|}}
===Why there is no real risk of a synthetic equity position being a secret custody position doing the taxman out of his money===
===Why there is no real risk of a [[synthetic equity]] position being a secret custody position doing the tax man out of his money===
 
Controversial view, perhaps, but the tax disposition which led to someone inventing the [[hypothetical broker dealer]] — a creature as beloved of the [[equity swap]] market as the [[reasonable man]] is of the [[common law]] — is, in this commentator’s untutored view, predicated on a fundamental misapprehension as to how a [[synthetic equity swap]], and the [[hedging]] and financing thereof, works. This fear of [[recharacterisation]] also disregards the [[IRS]]’s known acknowledgment that [[synthetic equity swap]]s are a thing; a bona fide class of transactions of genuine utility and wide use in the market.
====So what is the problem?====
The putative concern is that, should there be too close a connection between an equity swap and the means by which the swap [[dealer]] hedges it, thew dealer could be judged to be “acting as nominee owner” of the hedge for its client — a sort of undisclosed [[custodian]] — meaning the client becomes liable to that universe of stamp taxes and withholdings that apply to actual transactions in equity securities, but do not apply to swaps.
 
Now you might think the obvious answer here, for a revenue authority nursing this particular concern, would be to tax equity swaps the same way it taxes [[cash equity]] transactions, and sure enough, for the most part, this is what the IRS now does, by dint of Section [[871(m)]] of the [[Internal Revenue Code of 1986]]. But — US legislation being as susceptible to pork-barrel exceptions as ever — there are some obscure classes of security to which [[871(m)]] does not as yet apply — real estate investment trusts for example — so at the periphery this remains a live, if diminished, issue.
 
Hence the need for this essay. For, 871(m) or no, it is very hard to see how a delta-hedging swap dealer — especially a successful one, with a large portfolio of equity swaps — could be seen to be “acting as nominee owner” in a meaningful way, given how in practice it delta-hedges and finances its own physical positions.
 
===Hedging===
The concern here is that, though the master confirmation says the client has a [[derivative]] [[exposure]] only and that the [[dealer]] need not ever hold the underlying, by referencing “actual hedge execution” in the confirm the [[dealer]] may be telegraphing that, in practice it will always hold a cash position which will always correspond one-for-one to each client’s order. Thus, the dealer could be viewed as a “nominee owner”.  The argument runs like this:
*Even though it doesn’t have to, economically it would be foolish for a [[dealer]] not to [[hedge]] one-for-one.
*Since, logically<ref>Ah, but this ''isn’t logical, as we shall see.</ref> the dealer has no skin in the game and has a long the whole physical position for each client, it has no reason ''not'' to do as client asks in terms of voting on the shares and so on, plenty of commercial reasons that it should.
*The client therefore effectively controls that long position, getting the “duration” benefits of a continuous holding without being on the register of shareholders (which tbh the IRS doesn’t really care about) or liable for tax on the position (about which it assuredly does).
 
So for one thing, if that’s right, it’s hard to see how “[[hypothetical broker dealer]]” language fixes it, since it doesn’t change that economic reality. They’re just “[[magic words]]”. They don’t affect what happens in practice under the swap at all.  Show me a chap who relies on magical words, not economic reality, to get his tax treatment and I’ll show you a tax audit waiting to happen.
 
But in any case that ''isn’t'' right: it’s not the complete picture.  The dealer delta-hedges across its whole book, across all client positions, [[long]] and [[short]], as a single economic position, and then finances it in the market — lending it out — in both cases without reference to or the knowledge of the client.
 
Thus:
==== There is no delta-one hedge at the ''client'' level, even economically ====
The [[dealer]]’s existing hedge inventory is (a) constantly churning, (b) does not translate 1:1 with each individual long client position.  At any time, the [[dealer]]’s long exposure to a given cash security will equal its net long exposure across ''all'' clients, long and short, in the [[dealer]]’s whole book. The [[dealer]]’s  total holding is a function of its total client portfolio shape, not that of any individual client.
 
Therefore, if the book is 500 long and 300 short, the [[dealer]] will hold just 200 positions. If the 500 long clients want the [[dealer]] to vote their shares they’re — out of luck..
 
Nor does the [[dealer]] hold continuous positions in shares for the life of any transaction: It buys and sells every day to reflect changes in its net aggregate exposure caused by all client activity. It churns. Therefore:
*Individual clients couldn’t even with the [[dealer]]’s facilitation, exercise rights attaching continuous single holdings.
*All swap clients are at risk of hedging disruption ''every day'' whether or not any particular one has adjust its own position.
 
====The [[dealer]] lends out its aggregate long position by [[title transfer]] and usually doesn’t have a physical hedge at all====
And then we consider the financing operation of the [[dealer]]’s swap book into account. the [[dealer]] generally lend most, if not all, of the [[dealer]]’s net aggregate long position out into the market every day. It does this by [[title transfer]]. Where it can, it will lend the ''whole'' book out. It doesn’t, generally, hold any more physical securities hedges, as legal owner, at all.
                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                       
None of these things are consistent with a physical, enduring holding that could resemble a nominee ownership. It is clearly, categorically, an economic exposure only. The point is it is not that the [[dealer]] isn’t a nominee owner for a given client according to the legal theory, but that it isn’t a nominee, or any kind of owner, ''at all''. Generally speaking the [[dealer]] won’t hold shares at all. the [[dealer]]’ll hold economic exposures to shares. Even where the [[dealer]] do there is no 1:1 mapping between hedge position and share position.
 
3. The IRS position on the product generally
I am pretty sure the IRS understands this and is comfortable with it. This is why it introduced 871(m).
- High delta equity derivatives are a very big, liquid, and standardised product; the IRS understands it, accepts it, and has already taken direct measures to ensure they are taxed appropriately (ie 871(m)).
- The IRS’s goal is to stop brokers disguising effective nominee ownership arrangements, not to stop brokers paying exact delta one value of securities through genuine swap contracts.
o If it were to stop genuine swaps, then the “hypothetical broker dealer” language wouldn’t work anyway; the [[dealer]] would actually have to  adjust the delta away from 1 by a meaningful amount.
o That would significantly transform the product:  the very point of the synthetic equity product is to exactly replicate  the performance of a stock through derivatives.
- I can’t see what interest the IRS would have in, or to gain by, targeting legal “verbiage” of contracts to see if they catch brokers out by extracting an even more favourable tax treatment because one or other has forgotten to use the word “hypothetical” here or there. If that were a real risk, it would be far too high and the [[dealer]] should not be doing this business at all.

Revision as of 19:02, 20 March 2020

Hedge Funds & Prime Brokerage Anatomy™


There is no industry standard prime brokerage agreement, so this is not so much an anatomy as a collection of resources about an amorphous subject.
Hedge fund | AIFMD | Depositary | Prime broker | prime brokerage agreement | synthetic prime brokerage | margin lending | custody asset | CASS Anatomy | reuse & rehypothecation | hedge fund | leveraged alpha | greeks | short selling Index: Click to expand:

Comments? Questions? Suggestions? Requests? Insults? We’d love to 📧 hear from you.
Sign up for our newsletter.


Why there is no real risk of a synthetic equity position being a secret custody position doing the tax man out of his money

Controversial view, perhaps, but the tax disposition which led to someone inventing the hypothetical broker dealer — a creature as beloved of the equity swap market as the reasonable man is of the common law — is, in this commentator’s untutored view, predicated on a fundamental misapprehension as to how a synthetic equity swap, and the hedging and financing thereof, works. This fear of recharacterisation also disregards the IRS’s known acknowledgment that synthetic equity swaps are a thing; a bona fide class of transactions of genuine utility and wide use in the market.

So what is the problem?

The putative concern is that, should there be too close a connection between an equity swap and the means by which the swap dealer hedges it, thew dealer could be judged to be “acting as nominee owner” of the hedge for its client — a sort of undisclosed custodian — meaning the client becomes liable to that universe of stamp taxes and withholdings that apply to actual transactions in equity securities, but do not apply to swaps.

Now you might think the obvious answer here, for a revenue authority nursing this particular concern, would be to tax equity swaps the same way it taxes cash equity transactions, and sure enough, for the most part, this is what the IRS now does, by dint of Section 871(m) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1986. But — US legislation being as susceptible to pork-barrel exceptions as ever — there are some obscure classes of security to which 871(m) does not as yet apply — real estate investment trusts for example — so at the periphery this remains a live, if diminished, issue.

Hence the need for this essay. For, 871(m) or no, it is very hard to see how a delta-hedging swap dealer — especially a successful one, with a large portfolio of equity swaps — could be seen to be “acting as nominee owner” in a meaningful way, given how in practice it delta-hedges and finances its own physical positions.

Hedging

The concern here is that, though the master confirmation says the client has a derivative exposure only and that the dealer need not ever hold the underlying, by referencing “actual hedge execution” in the confirm the dealer may be telegraphing that, in practice it will always hold a cash position which will always correspond one-for-one to each client’s order. Thus, the dealer could be viewed as a “nominee owner”. The argument runs like this:

  • Even though it doesn’t have to, economically it would be foolish for a dealer not to hedge one-for-one.
  • Since, logically[1] the dealer has no skin in the game and has a long the whole physical position for each client, it has no reason not to do as client asks in terms of voting on the shares and so on, plenty of commercial reasons that it should.
  • The client therefore effectively controls that long position, getting the “duration” benefits of a continuous holding without being on the register of shareholders (which tbh the IRS doesn’t really care about) or liable for tax on the position (about which it assuredly does).

So for one thing, if that’s right, it’s hard to see how “hypothetical broker dealer” language fixes it, since it doesn’t change that economic reality. They’re just “magic words”. They don’t affect what happens in practice under the swap at all. Show me a chap who relies on magical words, not economic reality, to get his tax treatment and I’ll show you a tax audit waiting to happen.

But in any case that isn’t right: it’s not the complete picture. The dealer delta-hedges across its whole book, across all client positions, long and short, as a single economic position, and then finances it in the market — lending it out — in both cases without reference to or the knowledge of the client.

Thus:

There is no delta-one hedge at the client level, even economically

The dealer’s existing hedge inventory is (a) constantly churning, (b) does not translate 1:1 with each individual long client position. At any time, the dealer’s long exposure to a given cash security will equal its net long exposure across all clients, long and short, in the dealer’s whole book. The dealer’s total holding is a function of its total client portfolio shape, not that of any individual client.

Therefore, if the book is 500 long and 300 short, the dealer will hold just 200 positions. If the 500 long clients want the dealer to vote their shares they’re — out of luck..

Nor does the dealer hold continuous positions in shares for the life of any transaction: It buys and sells every day to reflect changes in its net aggregate exposure caused by all client activity. It churns. Therefore:

  • Individual clients couldn’t even with the dealer’s facilitation, exercise rights attaching continuous single holdings.
  • All swap clients are at risk of hedging disruption every day whether or not any particular one has adjust its own position.

The dealer lends out its aggregate long position by title transfer and usually doesn’t have a physical hedge at all

And then we consider the financing operation of the dealer’s swap book into account. the dealer generally lend most, if not all, of the dealer’s net aggregate long position out into the market every day. It does this by title transfer. Where it can, it will lend the whole book out. It doesn’t, generally, hold any more physical securities hedges, as legal owner, at all.

None of these things are consistent with a physical, enduring holding that could resemble a nominee ownership. It is clearly, categorically, an economic exposure only. The point is it is not that the dealer isn’t a nominee owner for a given client according to the legal theory, but that it isn’t a nominee, or any kind of owner, at all. Generally speaking the dealer won’t hold shares at all. the dealer’ll hold economic exposures to shares. Even where the dealer do there is no 1:1 mapping between hedge position and share position.

3. The IRS position on the product generally I am pretty sure the IRS understands this and is comfortable with it. This is why it introduced 871(m). - High delta equity derivatives are a very big, liquid, and standardised product; the IRS understands it, accepts it, and has already taken direct measures to ensure they are taxed appropriately (ie 871(m)). - The IRS’s goal is to stop brokers disguising effective nominee ownership arrangements, not to stop brokers paying exact delta one value of securities through genuine swap contracts. o If it were to stop genuine swaps, then the “hypothetical broker dealer” language wouldn’t work anyway; the dealer would actually have to adjust the delta away from 1 by a meaningful amount. o That would significantly transform the product: the very point of the synthetic equity product is to exactly replicate the performance of a stock through derivatives. - I can’t see what interest the IRS would have in, or to gain by, targeting legal “verbiage” of contracts to see if they catch brokers out by extracting an even more favourable tax treatment because one or other has forgotten to use the word “hypothetical” here or there. If that were a real risk, it would be far too high and the dealer should not be doing this business at all.

  1. Ah, but this isn’t logical, as we shall see.