Template:GMSLA compensation for mismanagement: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 6: Line 6:
On one hand, the definition of {{gmslaprov|Income}} is very wide:
On one hand, the definition of {{gmslaprov|Income}} is very wide:


''{{Template:GMSLA 2010 Income}}''
''{{Template:GMSLA 2010 Income}}''


On the other hand — and it pains me somewhat to lay some {{t|Latin}} on you, but I will — the [[ejusdem generis]] rule of interpretation says where general words (here, “distribution of [[Any type, kind or nature|any kind whatsoever]]”) follow specific words (“[[Dividend - Equity Derivatives Provision|dividends]], [[interest]]”), the general words are cover only objects similar in nature to those specific words. So the distribution should be of the same nature as interest or dividends.
On the other hand — and it pains me somewhat to lay some {{t|Latin}} on you, but I will — the [[ejusdem generis]] rule of interpretation says where general words (here, “distribution of [[Any type, kind or nature|any kind whatsoever]]”) follow specific words (“[[Dividend - Equity Derivatives Provision|dividends]], [[interest]]”), the general words are cover only objects similar in nature to those specific words. So the distribution should be of the same nature as interest or dividends.

Revision as of 17:14, 11 June 2019

Retrospective compensation for corporate mismanagement

An interesting question arises as to whether settlements or judgments reflecting corporate malfeasance by issuers of Loaned Securities or Collateral — and which manifest themselves in compensation payments to shareholders of record as of a certain date (and which falls during the term of a Loan) — qualify as “Income” under the 2010 GMSLA that must be manufactured back to the Lender.

Such disputes can take years — decades even — to iron out, can take any number of different forms and, if viewed as Income, represent a significant tail risk in a Borrower’s trading book.

On one hand, the definition of Income is very wide:

Income means any interest, dividends or other distributions of any kind whatsoever with respect to any Securities or Collateral;

On the other hand — and it pains me somewhat to lay some Latin on you, but I will — the ejusdem generis rule of interpretation says where general words (here, “distribution of any kind whatsoever”) follow specific words (“dividends, interest”), the general words are cover only objects similar in nature to those specific words. So the distribution should be of the same nature as interest or dividends.

So, is a court-mandated compensation for historical corporate malfeasance “of the same nature” as voluntarily declared dividend, intended by its issuer to reflect its own satisfactory stewardship of the corporation’s commercial affairs? The JC would argue that it is not. Quite the opposite, in fact: if we take it as read that one borrows securities to short-sell them in the market we see that the short-seller’s exact view is that the securities are overvalued: this is consistent with the theory that their issuer is mismanaging the company. The Short-seller bets that the truth will eventually come out and, when it does, the shares will fall in price. It can then buy them back, take a profit, and deliver them back to the Lender.

It can't be right that, where the short-seller is so right about this the Securities issuer is breaching its fiduciary duties to its shareholders, that it must compensate the Lender as a result.

But this puts the poor Lender in a sorry spot. Because it has lent the securities, it is not on the register as of the Income Record Date, so however you characterise that compensation payment, it can’t claim if from anyone. “The deal”, it will argue, “is that the Borrower should put me in the position I would have been in had I continued to hold the shares. I wasn’t expressing a view here. I stayed long the economic exposure of the stock. All I wanted was a lending fee.”

It is hard not to be sympathetic about this. Were the Borrower to have held the shares, it might even be prepared to make that ex gratia payment on the basis that it was a windfall: it knew the company was rubbish and made its money on the short sale. But there’s the rub: The borrower didn’t hold the shares. It sold them. That is why it Borrowed them in the first place.

So however you look at it, there’s a loser here. But in a sense, remember this is a windfall payment — some public spirited activist has jemmied some extra cash out of a reluctant issuer. Had it not done so no one would have been any the wiser.