Extreme prejudice: Difference between revisions
Amwelladmin (talk | contribs) No edit summary Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit |
Amwelladmin (talk | contribs) No edit summary |
||
(8 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{A|hr|}} | {{A|hr|}}{{d|{{PAGENAME}}|ɪksˈtriːm ˈprɛʤʊdɪs |n}} | ||
1. ''Employment'' (rare): End a useless employee’s employment without that employee’s consent, making a mental note never to hire anyone even vaguely resembling that person again. Hence: | |||
2. ''US military intelligence'': (''To terminate with'' ~) To tactically assassinate. Put out of his, and our, misery. | |||
=== On being cruel to be kind === | |||
We have canvassed the odd phenomenon of [[mediocrity drift]] whereby the feedback loops of [[lateral resignation]] and [[reduction in force]] induce an odd [[system effect]] whereby the parts of your workforce you are most anxious to retain progressively deteriorate in ''quality'', if not number. | |||
At this point you have categorically ''worsened'' your position. | Employment is not, naturally, an equilibrium state.<ref>And nor should it be, though it is made (regrettably) more stable by labour laws.</ref> There is a fragile sweet spot when master and servant both feel they are getting a reasonable return for their investment, but keeping near it requires constant attention, the way driving along a straight road still requires ''steering''. | ||
In a perfect world, one would do this by trimming and goosing salary expectations as circumstances and performance change — keep the carrot dangling, and often enough letting dobbin have a nibble on it — but, Lord only knows, it is not a perfect world. | |||
Hence these [[system effect]]s. | |||
Now you might be [[inclined]] to look at this and think, “well, still, this is a fine state of affairs: by [[Redundancy|pruning the truly dismal in job lots]], and letting the jumped-up and flighty go one at a time, we are nicely containing our costs within a range.” | |||
This would be true, were you not obliged to replace those who leave. In an organisation big enough to have its own [[human resources]] department,<ref>We have a theory that the point at which a firm acquires its own dedicated [[HR]] function is the point at which it is ''too'' big, whereupon it begins its sure descent into sclerotic middle age. “[[Middle management]]” is a contradiction in terms, after all.</ref> [[Parkinson’s law]] obtains: you probably ''don’t'' need to replace leavers — or at least ''wouldn’t'', if you could hang on to those few staff who got anything done. But these are, by self-selecting definition, your [[lateral quitter]]<nowiki/>s. | |||
The operating theory propelling a [[reduction in force]], fully honoured in the breach though it is, is that those put “[[At risk of redundancy|at risk]]” are functionally surplus to requirements and ''need not be replaced''. The clue is in the name: if you still need someone to do that role, it is not redundant, is it? | |||
But this is of course fatuous: except in times of existential crisis — once a decade or so — [[RIF]]s are a cheap way of trimming poor performers. | |||
But, still, it is a canny firm indeed who keeps all its stars and sheds only donkeys. If, after your RIF, you are still stuck will a dead-weight of work-shy plodders, do not expect them to take up the slack. You will need to back-fill departees, and — unlike your departing [[lateral quitter]]<nowiki/>s — you must pay them the going rate. | |||
At this point, you have categorically ''worsened'' your position. | |||
So herewith our premise. It may seem a bit Hobbesian. But firms should be ''more active in targeted termination''. It is for the better of ''everyone''. Even the terminated. | |||
===Quid pro quo=== | ===Quid pro quo=== | ||
Notwithstanding it being the ''essence'' of an HR department’s purpose, generally the good burghers of [[HR]] are no more curious about underperformance than they are about [[lateral quitter]]s. | |||
In recent times, egged on by loopy notions of [[stakeholder capitalism|a higher purpose]], HR teams have become swollen, and distracted from this core role, by theoretical questions of social justice. They have lost focus on their one job: ''making sure the staff are cutting mustard''. | |||
Thus, underwhelming staff are allowed, like earthen clods, to lie fallow for unfeasibly long periods, languishing in a pool of non-advancement, continuing to draw salaries, until finally tilled at one of the firm’s irregular mass [[RIF|culls]]. Here, many laggards and no small number of good ’uns, are dispensed with at once, more or less indiscriminately. | |||
Redundancy rounds are a lazy, cowardly way of getting rid of staff you should have actively managed out. A [[RIF]] let you dress up performance management as “resource reallocation”: something it really isn’t. Some of this squeamishness is down to well-meant but basically doltish workplace legislation. | |||
[[ | Staff of professional services firms — even the personal assistants — are the “[[QIB]]”s of the employment world. They are experienced, educated, biddable, they have easy access to professional advice and are perfectly capable of assessing and, for extended periods, bearing the risks of their own poor performance. | ||
They are also, as a class, grossly overpaid. | |||
So, spare your violins. For all their complaints of their working conditions, [[Magic circle law firm|magic circle]] [[Private practice lawyer|associates]] are not itinerant fruit pickers. They need neither the matronly eye of a benign union nor the kindly blanket of labour regulations designed to defend helpless pit-workers from rapacious robber barrons. ''Good'' staff shouldn’t want these rules. ''Bad'' staff shouldn’t be entitled to them. | |||
It would be for everyone’s good — except grifters and lousy employers — were the usual rules relaxed to encourage greater mobility. That might persuade more firms to crowbar the many fat birds off the thin branches in which they nest at the top of your tree. | |||
We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have | We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have it right: ''employment at will''. Well-meant formalistic barriers to removing staff have the unintended consequence of increasing barriers to ''hiring'' staff, since it is that much harder to reverse a duff hiring decision. | ||
Good staff build their own defences against mistreatment termination as they go: their contributions, their expertise, their institutional knowledge and their rich, informal networks make then to valuable to mistreat. But, if workplace regulation discourages firing, so does it discourage hiring, as firms will be slow to take on cretin risk they can’t then easily divest. | |||
This gives poor employers licence to treat good staff worse, as they have fewer options to leave. | |||
No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional [[diversity]]. Smart firms will ensure they have cultural and cognitive diversity because the universe of business is culturally diverse. Firms that don’t will go out of business. Q.E.D. | No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional [[diversity]]. Smart firms will ensure they have cultural and cognitive diversity because the universe of business is culturally diverse. Firms that don’t will go out of business. [[Q.E.D.]] | ||
End of day, professional services employers should not | End of day, professional services employers should not be a privatised welfare system for their staff. The defence against [[mediocrity drift]] is to ''quickly deal with laggers''. | ||
The first tool here is discretionary bonus. With this you can bring down cost and push the laggard into the safe zone. If you are flatlining on doughnuts, and you can’t figure out a way of redeploying said laggard, then have the conversation. Be clear, have it early. | |||
===Look after what you have=== | ===Look after what you have=== | ||
How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the ''good performers''. | How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the ''good performers''. | ||
Line 41: | Line 62: | ||
Another way of looking at that continuum is this: you pay poor employees more than they are worth to you, and good employees, ''less'' than than they are worth, ''expect to have crappy employees''. | Another way of looking at that continuum is this: you pay poor employees more than they are worth to you, and good employees, ''less'' than than they are worth, ''expect to have crappy employees''. | ||
{{sa}} | |||
*[[RIF]] | |||
*[[Lateral quitter]] | |||
*[[Silver bullet]] | |||
{{ref}} |
Latest revision as of 17:17, 4 November 2023
The Human Resources military-industrial complex
|
Extreme prejudice
ɪksˈtriːm ˈprɛʤʊdɪs (n.)
1. Employment (rare): End a useless employee’s employment without that employee’s consent, making a mental note never to hire anyone even vaguely resembling that person again. Hence:
2. US military intelligence: (To terminate with ~) To tactically assassinate. Put out of his, and our, misery.
On being cruel to be kind
We have canvassed the odd phenomenon of mediocrity drift whereby the feedback loops of lateral resignation and reduction in force induce an odd system effect whereby the parts of your workforce you are most anxious to retain progressively deteriorate in quality, if not number.
Employment is not, naturally, an equilibrium state.[1] There is a fragile sweet spot when master and servant both feel they are getting a reasonable return for their investment, but keeping near it requires constant attention, the way driving along a straight road still requires steering.
In a perfect world, one would do this by trimming and goosing salary expectations as circumstances and performance change — keep the carrot dangling, and often enough letting dobbin have a nibble on it — but, Lord only knows, it is not a perfect world.
Hence these system effects.
Now you might be inclined to look at this and think, “well, still, this is a fine state of affairs: by pruning the truly dismal in job lots, and letting the jumped-up and flighty go one at a time, we are nicely containing our costs within a range.”
This would be true, were you not obliged to replace those who leave. In an organisation big enough to have its own human resources department,[2] Parkinson’s law obtains: you probably don’t need to replace leavers — or at least wouldn’t, if you could hang on to those few staff who got anything done. But these are, by self-selecting definition, your lateral quitters.
The operating theory propelling a reduction in force, fully honoured in the breach though it is, is that those put “at risk” are functionally surplus to requirements and need not be replaced. The clue is in the name: if you still need someone to do that role, it is not redundant, is it?
But this is of course fatuous: except in times of existential crisis — once a decade or so — RIFs are a cheap way of trimming poor performers.
But, still, it is a canny firm indeed who keeps all its stars and sheds only donkeys. If, after your RIF, you are still stuck will a dead-weight of work-shy plodders, do not expect them to take up the slack. You will need to back-fill departees, and — unlike your departing lateral quitters — you must pay them the going rate.
At this point, you have categorically worsened your position.
So herewith our premise. It may seem a bit Hobbesian. But firms should be more active in targeted termination. It is for the better of everyone. Even the terminated.
Quid pro quo
Notwithstanding it being the essence of an HR department’s purpose, generally the good burghers of HR are no more curious about underperformance than they are about lateral quitters.
In recent times, egged on by loopy notions of a higher purpose, HR teams have become swollen, and distracted from this core role, by theoretical questions of social justice. They have lost focus on their one job: making sure the staff are cutting mustard.
Thus, underwhelming staff are allowed, like earthen clods, to lie fallow for unfeasibly long periods, languishing in a pool of non-advancement, continuing to draw salaries, until finally tilled at one of the firm’s irregular mass culls. Here, many laggards and no small number of good ’uns, are dispensed with at once, more or less indiscriminately.
Redundancy rounds are a lazy, cowardly way of getting rid of staff you should have actively managed out. A RIF let you dress up performance management as “resource reallocation”: something it really isn’t. Some of this squeamishness is down to well-meant but basically doltish workplace legislation.
Staff of professional services firms — even the personal assistants — are the “QIB”s of the employment world. They are experienced, educated, biddable, they have easy access to professional advice and are perfectly capable of assessing and, for extended periods, bearing the risks of their own poor performance.
They are also, as a class, grossly overpaid.
So, spare your violins. For all their complaints of their working conditions, magic circle associates are not itinerant fruit pickers. They need neither the matronly eye of a benign union nor the kindly blanket of labour regulations designed to defend helpless pit-workers from rapacious robber barrons. Good staff shouldn’t want these rules. Bad staff shouldn’t be entitled to them.
It would be for everyone’s good — except grifters and lousy employers — were the usual rules relaxed to encourage greater mobility. That might persuade more firms to crowbar the many fat birds off the thin branches in which they nest at the top of your tree.
We need to get over the stigma of dismissal. Here, our American friends have it right: employment at will. Well-meant formalistic barriers to removing staff have the unintended consequence of increasing barriers to hiring staff, since it is that much harder to reverse a duff hiring decision.
Good staff build their own defences against mistreatment termination as they go: their contributions, their expertise, their institutional knowledge and their rich, informal networks make then to valuable to mistreat. But, if workplace regulation discourages firing, so does it discourage hiring, as firms will be slow to take on cretin risk they can’t then easily divest.
This gives poor employers licence to treat good staff worse, as they have fewer options to leave.
No firm in its right mind — okay, okay, that leaves out many of them — will fire an outperformer: those in their wrong minds self-harm when they do. This applies, too, to functional diversity. Smart firms will ensure they have cultural and cognitive diversity because the universe of business is culturally diverse. Firms that don’t will go out of business. Q.E.D.
End of day, professional services employers should not be a privatised welfare system for their staff. The defence against mediocrity drift is to quickly deal with laggers.
The first tool here is discretionary bonus. With this you can bring down cost and push the laggard into the safe zone. If you are flatlining on doughnuts, and you can’t figure out a way of redeploying said laggard, then have the conversation. Be clear, have it early.
Look after what you have
How to stop this? Well, for one thing, focus your attention on your employees who deserve it: the good performers.
Try to stop them leaving. Do this by figuring out why they are leaving. There may be complicated sociological explanations, but for most places it will take no towering intellectual insight to figure it out. In broad strokes it boils down to: money, progression, and quality of work.
Another way of looking at that continuum is this: you pay poor employees more than they are worth to you, and good employees, less than than they are worth, expect to have crappy employees.
See also
References
- ↑ And nor should it be, though it is made (regrettably) more stable by labour laws.
- ↑ We have a theory that the point at which a firm acquires its own dedicated HR function is the point at which it is too big, whereupon it begins its sure descent into sclerotic middle age. “Middle management” is a contradiction in terms, after all.