Cheapest-to-deliver: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
No edit summary
 
(4 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 4: Line 4:


====Credit derivatives ====
====Credit derivatives ====
{{drop|A|r some point}} in the 1990s someone came up with the idea of credit derivatives. These are derivative contracts — principally the [[credit default swap]] — that allow investors to manage credit risk to debt instruments.  
{{drop|A|r some point}} in the 1990s someone came up with the idea of [[Credit derivative|credit derivatives]]. These contracts — principally the [[credit default swap]] — allow investors to manage the credit risk to those who owe them under [[Debt security|debt instruments]].  


[[Debt instrument]]s are funny in a number of ways: there is generally little upside volatility — they repay at par, so offer little scope for trips to the moon — a lot of potential downside volatility — they can go to zero, if the debtor fails — they come in all shapes and sizes: bonds, medium term notes, bilateral loans, syndicated loans, deposits —and due to the term nature of debt, no two debt instruments are economically (let alone legally) fungible. Each instrument treads its own, albeit correlated, value path.  
[[Debt instrument]]s come in all shapes and sizes — [[bond]]<nowiki/>s, [[Medium term note|medium term notes]], [[Loan|bilateral loan]]<nowiki/>s, syndicated loans, [[deposit]]<nowiki/>s — and have a number of characteristics: they have a stated term, at which they repay a fixed amount. Therefore, they offer little scope for “trips to the moon” but since, if the debtor fails, they can go to zero they do offer a lot of potential ''downside'' risk. Due to their term nature, no two debt instruments of the same debtor are economically (let alone legally) fungible. Each debt instrument treads its own, albeit correlated, value path.  


As such, the market is generally opaque and, “sticky”: debt instruments are illiquid in a way equities, which generally have none of those limitations, are not. By the same token some debt instruments — publicly quoted senior bonds — are a lot more liquid and transparent than others.
As such, the market for debt instruments is generally opaque and “sticky”: debt instruments are illiquid in a way equities, which have none of those limitations, are not.


You might be able to buy a put on quoted bond at a reasonable price, but good luck with a privately negotiated term loan.  
Now, some debt instruments, such as publicly quoted senior bonds, are a lot more liquid and transparent, and therefore hedgeable, than others: you can buy a “[[Put option|put]]” on a listed bond at a good price, but good luck doing that with a private loan.  


Since, except in a [[tail event|disaster scenario]], debt repayment values are predictable in date and amount (unlike equities or commodities) as long as your borrower doesnʼt blow up you will eventually get your money back, it usually doesnʼt matter much — but when it ''does'' matter, it matters ''a lot''. You are hedging against a crash, not a basic variation in value.<ref>this is why, despite dealing with an instrument further down the capital structure [[equity derivatives]] are curiously '' less '' concerned with default than are [[credit derivatives]]. </ref>
But since debt repayment values are predictable then, as long as your borrower doesnʼt blow up, you will eventually get your money back, so it usually doesnʼt matter much that you canʼt — but when it ''does'' matter, it matters ''a lot''. So when you buy debt repayment protection you are necessarily hedging against a crash not just a change in value.<ref>this is why, despite referencing an instrument further down the capital structure, [[equity derivatives]] are curiously '' less '' concerned with default than are [[credit derivatives]]. </ref>  


The [[credit default swap]] emerged as a neat way to manage that risk. To cover against losses on my private bilateral loan I could buy a credit derivative which would pay out if the borrower defaulted on its quoted debt (a public event I donʼt need to prove) and my counterparty must pay me a sum calculated on the estimated market price of a range of observable liquid instruments. A proxy for my loss: not perfect, but good enough
The [[credit default swap]] emerged as a neat way to manage that risk. To cover against losses on an illiquid private bilateral loan, you could buy a [[credit derivative]] referencing a publicly quoted debt instrument (whose failure, being public you did not need to prove) and your counterparty must pay you a sum calculated on the estimated market price of a range of observable liquid instruments. This is to be sure, only a proxy for your actual loss, but a lot better than nothing.
====Trades are zero-sum games====
 
Where a contract can be fully understood in monetary terms, expect the parties to do the utter bare minimum to discharge it.  
Now. A [[CDS]] is only better than a bond put if the instrument you hold is not an observable, liquid instrument that you can freely put to someone. If it is, just buy a put! But if it isnʼt, expect some wangling about how to ''value'' it. It is one thing setting the ''trigger'' for the default, another to chose the instrument by reference to which you calculate its magnitude.
 
Hence the titular “cheapest to deliver”: where a range of deliverable obligations are specified, the calculation agent — usually the Buyer — gas discretion as to which she will choose. ''She will choose the cheapest''
 
Whereupon a famous illustration arose. As the noughties wore on, CDS practitioners got more used to the idea that the CDS was a one-to-one cresit hedge for their positions, and whether by habit or for balancesheet reasons,because that is where all the liquidity was, or maybe just because CDS was hip, started to hedge liquid instruments —the kind for which you '' could buy a put — with CDS as well.
 
Being a “crash protection”<ref>I did ''not'' say “[[Potts opinion|insurance]]”.</ref> product, almost all CDS expired unexercised, so the embedded cheapest to deliver option wasnʼt obvious to credit protection sellers — typically buy side investors looking for yield enhancement. It ''was'' obvious to sell side CDS buyers, who made their P&L precisely by pricing protection they paid by reference to the “{{cddprov|Reference Obligation}}” but delta-hedging by reference to the cheapest to deliver of the “{{cddprov|Delivery Obligation}}s”. This mispricing became apparent when a torrent of {{cddprov|Credit Events}} thundered through the market, Sellers affected outrage when Buyers  referenced not the freshly-issued, publicly quoted, liquid senior bonds they expected, but rather obscure, deeply subordinated, perpetual notes that hadn’t traded since issue, in 1975, that they¹d never heard of, and which barely scraped into eligibility as {{cddprov|Deliverable Obligation}}s by some oversight in the drafting on the Confirmation.
 
Cue much litigation, but the real lesson: read trade documents with [[peril-sensitive sunglasses]]. (The other lesson is that [[credit derivative]]s are silly things, but that is a story for another day.)


These are “transactions”; [[Zero-sum game|zero-sum]], [[Finite and Infinite Games|finite games]] — neither side has any expectation beyond the competent performance of its literal terms. When that is done, all remaining expectations fall to zero. The parties can walk away and never meet again.
The credit derivatives market is a shadow of its former self.  


Transactions, so regarded, are “trades”: quid-pro-quo, “[[barter]]” exchanges between parties who may or may not, otherwise, even like each other. The equity of the bargain is completely contained in the exchange: once it is done no abiding trust or faithfulness remains or is expected.  
====Trades are zero-sum games====
So where a contract can be fully understood in monetary terms, expect the parties to do the utter bare minimum to discharge it.  Look out, in other words, for “cheapest to deliver” options.  


====Cheapest-to-deliver====
These contracts are “transactions”; [[Zero-sum game|zero-sum]], [[Finite and Infinite Games|finite games]] — neither side has any expectation beyond the competent performance of its literal terms. When that is done, all remaining expectations fall to zero. The parties can walk away and never meet again.
We should not, therefore,  be surprised if the person to whom we sold an [[Option|financial option]] exercises it to her own advantage. That is why she bought it. ''That was the deal''. So we draw our trade documentation to be clear and to ''avoid'' giving away unintended options.  


A famous example arose in the CDS market during the financial crisis. Credit derivatives designate a specific {{cddprov|Reference Obligation}} that triggers a {{cddprov|Credit Event}}, but a wider class of {{cddprov|Deliverable Obligation}}s that the {{cddprov|Buyer}} may use to value its credit loss should one happen. This gave Buyers a “cheapest-to-deliver” option and, when the world was in flames and everyone’s hair was on fire they exercised it, selecting the cheapest {{cddprov|Deliverable Obligation}}s they could find.
Recall the distinction [[David Graeber]] makes between ''[[barter]]'' and ''[[credit]]''. Barter is an interaction between hostiles who cannot afford to leave anything on the table; credit is an interaction between friends who can and ''should''.  


This should not have, but ''did'', surprise credit derivative ''Sellers''. When a torrent of {{cddprov|Credit Events}} thundered through the market, Sellers affected outraged when Buyers  referenced not the freshly-issued, publicly quoted, liquid senior bonds they expected, but rather obscure, deeply subordinated, perpetual notes that hadn’t traded since issue, in 1975, that they¹d never heard of, and which barely scraped into eligibility as {{cddprov|Deliverable Obligation}}s by some oversight in the drafting on the Confirmation.  
Transactions, so regarded, are “trades”: quid-pro-quo, “[[barter]]” exchanges between parties who may or may not, otherwise, even like each other. The equity of the bargain is completely contained in the exchange: once performed, no abiding trust or faithfulness remains or is expected.  


Cue much litigation, but the real lesson: read trade documents with peril-sensitive sunglasses. (The other lesson is that [[credit derivative]]s are silly things, but that is a story for another day.)
When we are trading, we should not be surprised when our counterparty exercises a cheapest to deliver option. (in the market a delta-hedged dealer does not ''have'' a market position, so will not care how its customer exercises her options.)  


====Relationship contracts are not zero-sum games====
But discrete trades are an unusual type of contract. Most commercial arrangements depend on trust. They operate the same way social relationships do, with ongoing, permanently undischarged “social debts” between the parties. These are the ties that bind, which make credit extension feasible. Those in an ongoing commercial relationship do not, if they know what is good for them, exercise cheapest to deliver options. work-to-rule; if there are errors or misunderstandings we are, within reason, forgiving of them. We allow each other flex: as long as we are making a return from the relationship we are happy to leave something on the table in the interests of the longer-term relationship.
But discrete trades are an unusual type of contract. Most commercial relationships (even trading ones) are based on trust. They operate the same way social relationships do, with ongoing, permanently undischarged “social debts” between the parties. These are the ties that bind, in which credit is possible. We do not work-to-rule; if there are errors or misunderstandings we are, within reason, forgiving of them. We allow each other flex: as long as we are making a return from the relationship we are happy to leave something on the table in the interests of the longer-term relationship.


====CDOs and cheapest-to-deliver====
====CDOs and cheapest-to-deliver====
Line 47: Line 54:
*[[Service level agreement]]
*[[Service level agreement]]
*[[Worst reasonable endeavours]]
*[[Worst reasonable endeavours]]
{{Ref}}

Latest revision as of 13:24, 20 September 2024

The Jolly Contrarian’s Glossary
The snippy guide to financial services lingo.™
Index — Click the ᐅ to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

Cheapest-to-deliver
/ˈʧiːpɪst tuː dɪˈlɪvə/ (adj.)

Of the range of valid means of performing a contract, the one that will cost you the least and irritate your customer the most should you choose it.

Credit derivatives

Ar some point in the 1990s someone came up with the idea of credit derivatives. These contracts — principally the credit default swap — allow investors to manage the credit risk to those who owe them under debt instruments.

Debt instruments come in all shapes and sizes — bonds, medium term notes, bilateral loans, syndicated loans, deposits — and have a number of characteristics: they have a stated term, at which they repay a fixed amount. Therefore, they offer little scope for “trips to the moon” but since, if the debtor fails, they can go to zero they do offer a lot of potential downside risk. Due to their term nature, no two debt instruments of the same debtor are economically (let alone legally) fungible. Each debt instrument treads its own, albeit correlated, value path.

As such, the market for debt instruments is generally opaque and “sticky”: debt instruments are illiquid in a way equities, which have none of those limitations, are not.

Now, some debt instruments, such as publicly quoted senior bonds, are a lot more liquid and transparent, and therefore hedgeable, than others: you can buy a “put” on a listed bond at a good price, but good luck doing that with a private loan.

But since debt repayment values are predictable then, as long as your borrower doesnʼt blow up, you will eventually get your money back, so it usually doesnʼt matter much that you canʼt — but when it does matter, it matters a lot. So when you buy debt repayment protection you are necessarily hedging against a crash — not just a change in value.[1]

The credit default swap emerged as a neat way to manage that risk. To cover against losses on an illiquid private bilateral loan, you could buy a credit derivative referencing a publicly quoted debt instrument (whose failure, being public you did not need to prove) and your counterparty must pay you a sum calculated on the estimated market price of a range of observable liquid instruments. This is to be sure, only a proxy for your actual loss, but a lot better than nothing.

Now. A CDS is only better than a bond put if the instrument you hold is not an observable, liquid instrument that you can freely put to someone. If it is, just buy a put! But if it isnʼt, expect some wangling about how to value it. It is one thing setting the trigger for the default, another to chose the instrument by reference to which you calculate its magnitude.

Hence the titular “cheapest to deliver”: where a range of deliverable obligations are specified, the calculation agent — usually the Buyer — gas discretion as to which she will choose. She will choose the cheapest

Whereupon a famous illustration arose. As the noughties wore on, CDS practitioners got more used to the idea that the CDS was a one-to-one cresit hedge for their positions, and whether by habit or for balancesheet reasons,because that is where all the liquidity was, or maybe just because CDS was hip, started to hedge liquid instruments —the kind for which you could buy a put — with CDS as well.

Being a “crash protection”[2] product, almost all CDS expired unexercised, so the embedded cheapest to deliver option wasnʼt obvious to credit protection sellers — typically buy side investors looking for yield enhancement. It was obvious to sell side CDS buyers, who made their P&L precisely by pricing protection they paid by reference to the “Reference Obligation” but delta-hedging by reference to the cheapest to deliver of the “Delivery Obligations”. This mispricing became apparent when a torrent of Credit Events thundered through the market, Sellers affected outrage when Buyers referenced not the freshly-issued, publicly quoted, liquid senior bonds they expected, but rather obscure, deeply subordinated, perpetual notes that hadn’t traded since issue, in 1975, that they¹d never heard of, and which barely scraped into eligibility as Deliverable Obligations by some oversight in the drafting on the Confirmation.

Cue much litigation, but the real lesson: read trade documents with peril-sensitive sunglasses. (The other lesson is that credit derivatives are silly things, but that is a story for another day.)

The credit derivatives market is a shadow of its former self.

Trades are zero-sum games

So where a contract can be fully understood in monetary terms, expect the parties to do the utter bare minimum to discharge it. Look out, in other words, for “cheapest to deliver” options.

These contracts are “transactions”; zero-sum, finite games — neither side has any expectation beyond the competent performance of its literal terms. When that is done, all remaining expectations fall to zero. The parties can walk away and never meet again.

Recall the distinction David Graeber makes between barter and credit. Barter is an interaction between hostiles who cannot afford to leave anything on the table; credit is an interaction between friends who can and should.

Transactions, so regarded, are “trades”: quid-pro-quo, “barter” exchanges between parties who may or may not, otherwise, even like each other. The equity of the bargain is completely contained in the exchange: once performed, no abiding trust or faithfulness remains or is expected.

When we are trading, we should not be surprised when our counterparty exercises a cheapest to deliver option. (in the market a delta-hedged dealer does not have a market position, so will not care how its customer exercises her options.)

But discrete trades are an unusual type of contract. Most commercial arrangements depend on trust. They operate the same way social relationships do, with ongoing, permanently undischarged “social debts” between the parties. These are the ties that bind, which make credit extension feasible. Those in an ongoing commercial relationship do not, if they know what is good for them, exercise cheapest to deliver options. work-to-rule; if there are errors or misunderstandings we are, within reason, forgiving of them. We allow each other flex: as long as we are making a return from the relationship we are happy to leave something on the table in the interests of the longer-term relationship.

CDOs and cheapest-to-deliver

Now: zero-sum contracts like this are — should be — very much the exception. Commercial arrangements — even those governing the trading of zero-sum financial contracts — are not like that. They work best where the counterparties trust each other. This is the difference between a single round and an iterated series of the “prisoner’s dilemma”.

Now this “cheapest-to-deliver” concept is no long-lost curio from the history of the structured credit market. Being a foundational premise of the agency problem, it is in turn a cornerstone of any service industry. You know, such as the financial services industry, or the legal services industry, and the consulting industry.

Any organisation to whom one outsources one’s operational framework for the long term will measure its success by how closely it can tack, on average, to the bare minimum whilst not too regularly over-stepping it.

See also

References

  1. this is why, despite referencing an instrument further down the capital structure, equity derivatives are curiously less concerned with default than are credit derivatives.
  2. I did not say “insurance”.