Template:M summ Pledge GMSLA 11: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 7: Line 7:
Anyway, the process on any {{pgmslaprov|Event of Default}} — but let’s presume for the sake of simplicity it is one committed by the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} — is this:
Anyway, the process on any {{pgmslaprov|Event of Default}} — but let’s presume for the sake of simplicity it is one committed by the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} — is this:
*All {{pgmslaprov|Loan}}s are all accelerated, and the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} is liable to return {{eqderivprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}} as at the time of default. It won’t be able to of course, for the reasons given above.  
*All {{pgmslaprov|Loan}}s are all accelerated, and the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} is liable to return {{eqderivprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}} as at the time of default. It won’t be able to of course, for the reasons given above.  
*So the {{pgmslaprov|Lender}} works out the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}} of the {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}. It does this selling {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}, getting and averaging quotes for the sale<ref>''Or purchase, but as discussed only an idiot Borrower would use the close-out provisions to terminate a Loan where a Lender defaulted.</ref> of {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}, or, if it can’t, or the quotes seem out of whack, it can come up with its own opinion of their value, factor in any notional {{pgmslaprov|Transaction Costs}}, and use that. Expect an aggrieved Lender to confabulate some difficulty in getting good quotes and to go for using its own opinion more often than you’d necessarily expect. The {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}}’s bust, so what does he care, right?
*So the {{pgmslaprov|Lender}} works out the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}} of the {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}. It does this selling {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}, getting and averaging quotes for the sale<ref>''Or'' purchase, but as discussed only an idiot {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} would use the close-out provisions to terminate a {{pgmslaprov|Loan}} where a {{pgmslaprov|Lender}} defaulted.</ref> of {{pgmslaprov|Equivalent}} {{pgmslaprov|Securities}}, or, if it can’t, or the quotes seem out of whack, it can come up with its own opinion of their value, factor in any notional {{pgmslaprov|Transaction Costs}}, and use that. Expect an aggrieved Lender to confabulate some difficulty in getting good quotes and to go for using its own opinion more often than you’d necessarily expect. The {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}}’s bust, so what does he care, right?
*The Lender can also confabulate I mean reasonably calculate its legal costs of closing out, and add those to the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}}
*The Lender can also confabulate I mean reasonably calculate its legal costs of closing out, and add those to the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}}
*Lastly, it can set off against amounts it owes to the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} but, unlike under the title transfer {{gmsla}}, there aren’t likely to be many, seeing as the Collateral leg is not a title transfer collateral arrangement and is still technically owned by the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}}. But not for long.  
*Lastly, it can set off against amounts it owes to the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}} but, unlike under the title transfer {{gmsla}}, there aren’t likely to be many, seeing as the Collateral leg is not a title transfer collateral arrangement and is still technically owned by the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}}. But not for long.  


Unlike under the {{gmsla}} the netting mechanic doesn’t ''do'' much. There isn’t much to net. The Lender has a large claim against the Borrower, for the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}}, and it satisfies this by enforcing security under a separate {{pgmslaprov|Security Deed}}.
Unlike under the {{gmsla}} the netting mechanic doesn’t ''do'' much. There isn’t much to net. The {{pgmslaprov|Lender}} has a large claim against the {{pgmslaprov|Borrower}}, for the {{pgmslaprov|Default Market Value}}, and it satisfies this by enforcing its security under a separate {{pgmslaprov|Security Deed}}. To reiterate what should be obvious, under a pledged collateral arrangement the credit mitigation is by way of [[Security interest|security]], not [[Close-out netting|netting]].

Revision as of 11:49, 24 June 2020

So, how does default and close-out differ between title transfer and pledge versions of the GMSLA, then? Not as much as you might think. The mechanism for determining who owes what is broadly the same but, since the Borrower hasn’t parted company with the Collateral it has pledged — yet — and byt the theory of the game the pledged Collateral is sitting quietlky in a segregated account with a triparty custodian, ready to be returned or seized and liquidated, as the circumstances require, all of the Securities valuation mechanisms focus on the Loaned Securities leg of the transaction, since the Borrower won’t, if it has a scooby doo what it is doing, be holding the Loaned Securities at any time during the Loan. It will have sold them short.

It only really comes in to play if the Borrower has defaulted

If the Lender has defaulted, you generally wouldn’t call an Event of Default under a 2018 Pledge GMSLA. There is no need: the Borrower just returns the Loaned Securities, security is released from its pledged Collateral and we all carry on our sedated ways. I mean sedate ways. Sure, if you’re a masochist you could invoke the default process of Paragraph 11, but why would you? The Loan is terminable at will; if you do want out, just terminate it and give Equivalent Securities back, and the security is released from your pledged Collateral. Far easier.

If the Borrower has defaulted, de l’autre main, there is the matter of getting Equivalent Securities back which (a) by our theory, the Borrower hasn’t got, and would therefore have to go out to the market and get, and (b) the Borrower couldn’t, without the permission of its insolvency administrator, give back to you even if it did have one. Therefore the netting and close out provisions are quite handy.

How the closeout works

Anyway, the process on any Event of Default — but let’s presume for the sake of simplicity it is one committed by the Borrower — is this:

  • All Loans are all accelerated, and the Borrower is liable to return Equivalent Securities as at the time of default. It won’t be able to of course, for the reasons given above.
  • So the Lender works out the Default Market Value of the Equivalent Securities. It does this selling Equivalent Securities, getting and averaging quotes for the sale[1] of Equivalent Securities, or, if it can’t, or the quotes seem out of whack, it can come up with its own opinion of their value, factor in any notional Transaction Costs, and use that. Expect an aggrieved Lender to confabulate some difficulty in getting good quotes and to go for using its own opinion more often than you’d necessarily expect. The Borrower’s bust, so what does he care, right?
  • The Lender can also confabulate I mean reasonably calculate its legal costs of closing out, and add those to the Default Market Value
  • Lastly, it can set off against amounts it owes to the Borrower but, unlike under the title transfer 2010 GMSLA, there aren’t likely to be many, seeing as the Collateral leg is not a title transfer collateral arrangement and is still technically owned by the Borrower. But not for long.

Unlike under the 2010 GMSLA the netting mechanic doesn’t do much. There isn’t much to net. The Lender has a large claim against the Borrower, for the Default Market Value, and it satisfies this by enforcing its security under a separate Security Deed. To reiterate what should be obvious, under a pledged collateral arrangement the credit mitigation is by way of security, not netting.

  1. Or purchase, but as discussed only an idiot Borrower would use the close-out provisions to terminate a Loan where a Lender defaulted.