Terminating a finance contract

From The Jolly Contrarian
Revision as of 13:43, 28 October 2024 by Amwelladmin (talk | contribs)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
The ISDA Master Agreement

The Jolly Contrarian holds forth™

You’re off, sunshine

Resources and Navigation

Index: Click to expand:

Navigation

See ISDA Comparison for a comparison between the 1992 ISDA and the 2002 ISDA.
The Varieties of ISDA Experience
Subject 2002 (wikitext) 1992 (wikitext) 1987 (wikitext)
Preamble Pre Pre Pre
Interpretation 1 1 1
Obligns/Payment 2 2 2
Representations 3 3 3
Agreements 4 4 4
EODs & Term Events 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSTCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityFMTax EventTEUMCEUMATE 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSTCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityTax EventTEUMCEUMATE 5 Events of Default: FTPDBreachCSDMisrepDUSSCross DefaultBankruptcyMWA Termination Events: IllegalityTax EventTEUMCEUM
Early Termination 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculations; Payment DatePayments on ETSet-off 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculationsPayments on ETSet-off 6 Early Termination: ET right on EODET right on TEEffect of DesignationCalculationsPayments on ET
Transfer 7 7 7
Contractual Currency 8 8 8
Miscellaneous 9 9 9
Offices; Multibranch Parties 10 10 10
Expenses 11 11 11
Notices 12 12 12
Governing Law 13 13 13
Definitions 14 14 14
Schedule Schedule Schedule Schedule
Termination Provisions Part 1 Part 1 Part 1
Tax Representations Part 2 Part 2 Part 2
Documents for Delivery Part 3 Part 3 Part 3
Miscellaneous Part 4 Part 4 Part 4
Other Provisions Part 5 Part 5 Part 5
Index: Click to expand:

Commerce gives the lie to the idea that life is a zero-sum game. This was Adam Smith’s great liberating insight: life need not be nasty, brutish and short after all. Each of us will only strike a bargain if, on our own terms, we will be better off as a result. That being the case, there is no logical end to a commercial relationship: it is an infinite game. If we are flexible enough, open-minded enough, and good enough at playing infinite games we can keep this positive feedback loop of mutual benefit going indefinitely. Infinitely, even.

Therefore, we wish our relationships well, pray Godspeed for their long and fruity lives and, should things come to an end game, a peaceful ultimate transition from the flush of vital ardour into the restful stasis of the hereafter. But we know this is not always possible. Things do not always work out.

Therefore, we pack our trunk with tools and weapons with which, if needed, we can engineer an exit. There is no more sacred a time in the lives of our commercial contracts than their departure from the earthly clutch. There are a host of different ways this can happen. While lawyers rabbit on about these things in the hypothetical specific, in general terms we do not talk about them enough. Below, I comes over all over-analytical and count the ways an agreement can meet its maker.

Customers and service providers

Now the great majority of financial contracts are between a “provider” on one side — a bank, broker or dealer who provides a service, broadly described: money outright, finance against an asset, or a financial exposure — and a “customer” on the other who buys that service. The customer is, as ever, king: the services exist for her benefit exclusively: the provider’s only interest is managing its own exposure that comes from providing that service and, as it does, extracting some fee, commission or economic rent by way of consideration.

This is to say, “providers” do not mean to be economically “the other side” of the services they provide. They are, loosely, intermediaries. Agents. They do not take a direct opposite exposure. All being well, they are indifferent to how well the instruments they provide perform — so, as long as they manage their own risks and costs, and as long as their customers remain in fine fettle, they should never need to terminate their services. Indeed, they should want to keep them going, vigorously, seeing how that is how they earn a crust.

So expectations on either side of a service contract are different: the customer has market risk and it is her prerogative to go off risk as she sees fit. She can exit whenever she wants, by paying the provider’s outstanding fees and whatever it needs to terminate the arrangements it made to provide the service in the first place: its “breakage costs”.

But all else being equal, the provider cannot just exit without the customer’s permission. A financial contract with a fixed term, therefore, binds the provider but not the customer to that term.

But things can change. The customer’s financial outlook may darken. She may not be as good as her word. The regulatory environment may change, making the services harder or more expensive to provide.

Hence, the provider must have a set of “weapons” it can use to get out of such a term arrangement where it can no longer be sure of its expected return. These fall into a bunch of different categories, as we shall see:

Categories of termination

We would put these “termination scenarios” into three categories: “without cause[1]; unforeseen external events and counterparty failure. This last category — which we might also label “default” — in turn breaks into two: direct misbehaviour and indirect credit deterioration.

There is also an odd category of pseudo-termination rights that some regulated financial institutions must have, but would never intend to use which, curiously, relate to concerns about its own solvency.

“Without cause”

Terminations “without cause” arise just because — no fault, no pressing need; just a gradual drifting apart of interests. As we grow in life, the things we value change. Passions of youth dampen, we tend more towards songs of experience than those of innocent exuberance, and we sing those to a different tune. Here we prescribe a notice period long enough to allow our counterparty to make alternative arrangements it needs to keep its own house in order, but otherwise, we wish each other well and carry along on our way. These will generally be “clean-up” rights and they will exist under framework contracts, not specific transactions, and they will be expressed not to impact on the validity of in-flight services.

They are mainly of use to clear out low-value and dormant clients from the administrative record: there may be ongoing credit sanctioning or KYC obligations that the firm would rather not have to keep carrying out on a customer that no longer transacts any business.

“Pseudo-termination rights”

Where you do see dealer rights to terminate on notice without cause these will typically be pseudo-termination rights: here a regulated institution must have the power to terminate transactions for formalistic or regulatory capital reasons, even though it never expects to actually use them.[2] For example, a dealer’s right to terminate a synthetic equity derivative contract on notice. This entitles the dealer to treat the equity derivative exposure as a “short-term obligation” for regulatory purposes — because it could get out, if it wanted to— and this is enough to get optimised regulatory capital treatment. But a dealer having such a right is a different thing from a dealer ever in its right mind actually exercising it. It might be forced to, in the direst of circumstances (where its own survival was threatened) — but in that case — the dealer would be teetering — and the customers would likely long since have moved their positions away in any case.

“Termination Events”: regrettable, but no-one’s fault

It is in the nature of uncertainty that unexpected things can happen, Thanks to the machination of events beyond the knowledge or control of either party. Force majeure, changes in law, changes in taxation and regulatory capital treatment can make the continued provision of a service uneconomic or impractical.

These events, under the ISDA framework, are described as Termination Events. They typically are measured Transaction-by-Transaction, so do not have the necessary consequence of shutting down all exposure under the agreement in one fell swoop; only under those Transactions which are directly affected.

Secondly, there is generally more flexibility and leeway granted for the parties to explore workarounds and solutions to avoid having to terminate transactions, seeing as no one is at fault.

Thirdly, the ultimate replacement costs of the transaction will be situated at pure mid-market rather than on the dealer's side of the market, again reflecting the fact that no one is at fault. The suite of ISDA Termination Events have that quality of not being the Affected Party’s fault as such: Illegality; Force Majeure Event; Tax Event; Tax Event Upon Merger and Credit Event Upon Merger.

“Default Events”: do we have a problem here?

Then there are termination rights that flow from something untoward about your counterparty. This being a contract, the main category of “untoward facts” about your counterparty will be things it is meant to do by the express terms of the contract but it has failed to: call these performance failures.

Performance failures

These tend to be direct and uncontroversial: the classic is Failure to Pay or Deliver. There could not be an obligation more “of the essence” to a contract than payment or delivery of what you promised when you promised it. Ninety-five per cent of all close-outs — yes, I did just make that number up out of thin air, but I challenge you to disprove it — are triggered by a Failure to Pay or Deliver. Given that this is the weapon of choice for almost all closeouts, how heavily do you think it is negotiated?

Not at all.

There is, indeed, an inverse relationship between how long you will have to argue about a given close-out right and how likely you are to ever have to use it.

The other direct performance failures are by order of how quickly you can accelerate them:

Itchy Trigger Finger Guide
Event of Default Section Grace period
Repudiation of Agreement 5(a)(ii)(2) (Defaulting Party) or 5(a)(iii)(3) (Credit Support Provider) None.
Misrepresentation 5(a)(iv) None.
Credit Support Default (Total failure) 5(a)(iii)(2) None.
Failure to Pay or Deliver 5(a)(i) One Local Business Day after due date.
Breach of Agreement 5(a)(ii)(1) 30 days after notice of default.
Credit Support Default (direct default) 5(a)(iii)(1) Expiry of grace period in Credit Support Document.
Credit Events

There are a between three and four (depending on how you look at them) indirect Events of Default, that Do not require direct default under the Izda but rather are triggered by a collapse in the defaulting parties creditworthiness. These are Default Under Specified Transaction and Cross Default — being defaults under a Defaulting Party’s other financial arrangements, Bankruptcy and Merger Without Assumption — though You could also consider that a direct failure under the present contract as well.

Being less directly connected with the performance of the ISDA itself, these “credit” Events of Default have the potential for sod’s law. Cross Default particularly — JC has a long and overblown article about that — but there are aspects of the Bankruptcy (especially Automatic Early Termination) that have the potential for severe unintended consequences.

See also

References

  1. You hear these described as “no-fault” terminations, but there is no fault in a termination brought about by unforeseen externalities, either.
  2. See here Automatic Early Termination, which is an extreme example of such pseudo termination right: in that it triggers automatically. Much more to say about that on the AET page.