Employment derivatives: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|myth|{{image|Ironmountain1|jpg|}}}}{{d|Employment derivatives|/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/|n|}}
{{a|myth|{{image|Ironmountain1|jpg|}}}}{{d|Employment derivatives|/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/|n|}}A financial instrument developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, {{author|Hunter Barkley}}.
A financial instrument developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, {{author|Hunter Barkley}}.
====Genesis====
====Genesis====
{{Drop|W|hen midway through}} midway through his customary annual rant about the meaningless of his life and meagreness of his pay packet, it struck Barkley — an amateur [[fi-fi]] novelist and financial services naturalist — that just as the variable cost of his own employment was a material, unhedged contingency in his own life — Barkley believed himself, rightly, to be short a very ugly [[option]] to the Man — so too was everyone else’s in including, on the other side of the trade and at far greater scale, his employer’s.
{{Drop|W|hen midway through}} midway through his customary annual rant about the meaningless of his life as viewed through the lens of his pay packet, it struck Barkley — an amateur [[fi-fi]] novelist, financial services naturalist and tiresome windbag, not in that order — that just as his own fortunes at work were a material, unhedged contingency in his life having little to do with how good he was at it (his work, or life for that matter), so too were everyone else’s.  


A good-sized bank, he reasoned, would have an annual ''variance'' in employee compensation, without accounting for any ''changes'' in employment, in the billions of dollars.<ref>The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%</ref>
This included, at far greater scale, his employer. Barkley believed himself, rightly, to be short an ugly [[option]] to the Man. But by the same token a good-sized bank would have an annual ''variance'' in its total wage bill, even before accounting for ''changes'' in in its staff, in the ''billions'' of dollars.<ref>The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%</ref>


This ''variable'' cost of employment had little to do with the bank’s own performance, let alone that of its employees, and a lot to with ''everyone else’s'' performance. The ''market''. Hence [[Human resources|human capital management]] staff are apt to talk about “benchmarking”, as if there is some indexed rate.  
This variance bore little relation to the bank’s own performance, none to its employees, and a lot with ''everyone else’s'' performance. The ''market''. [[Human resources|Human capital management]] trading staff were apt to talk about “benchmarking”, as if there were some indexed rate.  


''Perhaps there should be'', reasoned Barkley.  
''Perhaps there should be'', reasoned Barkley. It was easy enough to calculate this variance, but ''knowing'' about it was a different thing to ''managing'' it. 


A firm having a bad year while its competitors feasted had no option but to hike pay to stop flush rivals piratically raiding its meagre stocks of [[human capital]]. By the same token, a firm that was knocking the ball out of the park while its competitors floundered, did not need to pay its own staff outsized bonuses. Where were they going to go?  
Barkley reasoned that different types of firm were “long” or “short” the babbling hysteria drove the employment market.  Barkley called the measure of this “madness” characteristic ''π<ref>From the Greek παράνοια, (''paranoia''). It was also pleasing that it conveyed sentiments of going around in a circle, running on a hamster wheel and so on, all of which Barkley recognised to be fundamental properties of the employment relationship.</ref>''. Upon its onset, “legacy”, “bricks-and-mortar”, “trad-fi” firms were typically short ''π'' and start-ups long. As the lunacy tailed off and employment relations [[Mean reversion|reverted to mean]], the ''π'' curve would invert. If one could only match off a long and a short firm, they each could hedge changes in π.
 
==== The first ERS ====
{{Drop|T|he first so-called}} [[employment rate swap]] was thereby conceived, between sleepy, ops-heavy mid-market broker [[Wickliffe Hampton]], at the time losing hundreds of compliance and onboarding staff each month, and [[lexrifyly]], a [[legaltech]] startup darling with no product, business model, customers or plan but flush with stupid amounts of VC cash, a great [[Microsoft PowerPoint|deck]] and an unshakable conviction in the wisdom of goosing its burn-rate by hiring lots of staff. 
 
One evening over canapes Wickliffe Hampton’s Chief Operating Officer Anita Dochter had been bellyaching to her  old friend and former trainee, now lexrifyly’s CEO, [[Cass Mälstrom]].
 
“But we actually ''need'' the staff,” she complained. “They actually do productive things for us. But unless we pay ''your'' stupid rates, which we cannot afford to do — and give them free fruit, working from home and a soft play area — they won’t stay with us. By contrast, you, right now, don’t need any staff: you simply need to show you are clever, imaginative and on point doing fashionably insane things. This does not require actual staff. If you are not actually hiring anyone, you could be hedging your employment rate risk of not doing so.
 
As luck would have it, Hunter Barkley was waiting tables that evening and overhead the conversation. He presented them with a pitch book with the check:
 
For an initial period of three years, Wickliffe would pay its wage bill for its entire operations team in London, controlled for performance, to lexrifyly. In return, lexrifyly would pay its projected wage budget for an equivalent sized-team to Wickliffe Hampton.<ref>This was slightly complicated as it was denominated in [[crypto]] and needed to be converted back to Sterling.  </ref> A firm having a bad year while its competitors feasted had no option but to hike pay to stop flush rivals piratically raiding its meagre stocks of [[human capital]]. By the same token, a firm that was knocking the ball out of the park while its competitors floundered, did not need to pay its own staff outsized bonuses. Where were they going to go?  


Legend has it, should she ever be asked for a raise, the [[Vampire Squid]]’s fearsome [[GC]] would theatrically throw open a draw stuffed with unsolicited resumes. “I am sure we’ll find someone to do your job if you’re too good for it.”
Legend has it, should she ever be asked for a raise, the [[Vampire Squid]]’s fearsome [[GC]] would theatrically throw open a draw stuffed with unsolicited resumes. “I am sure we’ll find someone to do your job if you’re too good for it.”
Line 20: Line 30:
Enter Barkley’s invention: [[employment rate swap|employment rate swaps]] promised to change that by tanking lateral movements — which were necessarily highly entropic in that they cost a lot in transaction friction, institutional leakage and so on and which could be avoided by just paying the employees more.
Enter Barkley’s invention: [[employment rate swap|employment rate swaps]] promised to change that by tanking lateral movements — which were necessarily highly entropic in that they cost a lot in transaction friction, institutional leakage and so on and which could be avoided by just paying the employees more.


The first [[employment rate swap]] was between the mid-market broker [[Wickliffe Hampton]] and then start-up darling [[lexrifyly]]. WH swapped its discretionary pool for Lexrifyly’s — complicated cross-currency issues as it was denominated in [[crypto]].


The banks could sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the bother of having to hedge themselves.
The banks could sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the bother of having to hedge themselves.

Revision as of 15:10, 12 April 2024

Myths and legends of the market
The JC’s guide to the foundational mythology of the markets.™
Ironmountain1.jpg
Index: Click to expand:

Comments? Questions? Suggestions? Requests? Insults? We’d love to 📧 hear from you.
Sign up for our newsletter.

Employment derivatives
/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/ (n.)
A financial instrument developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, Hunter Barkley.

Genesis

When midway through midway through his customary annual rant about the meaningless of his life as viewed through the lens of his pay packet, it struck Barkley — an amateur fi-fi novelist, financial services naturalist and tiresome windbag, not in that order — that just as his own fortunes at work were a material, unhedged contingency in his life having little to do with how good he was at it (his work, or life for that matter), so too were everyone else’s.

This included, at far greater scale, his employer. Barkley believed himself, rightly, to be short an ugly option to the Man. But by the same token a good-sized bank would have an annual variance in its total wage bill, even before accounting for changes in in its staff, in the billions of dollars.[1]

This variance bore little relation to the bank’s own performance, none to its employees, and a lot with everyone else’s performance. The market. Human capital management trading staff were apt to talk about “benchmarking”, as if there were some indexed rate.

Perhaps there should be, reasoned Barkley. It was easy enough to calculate this variance, but knowing about it was a different thing to managing it.

Barkley reasoned that different types of firm were “long” or “short” the babbling hysteria drove the employment market. Barkley called the measure of this “madness” characteristic π[2]. Upon its onset, “legacy”, “bricks-and-mortar”, “trad-fi” firms were typically short π and start-ups long. As the lunacy tailed off and employment relations reverted to mean, the π curve would invert. If one could only match off a long and a short firm, they each could hedge changes in π.

The first ERS

The first so-called employment rate swap was thereby conceived, between sleepy, ops-heavy mid-market broker Wickliffe Hampton, at the time losing hundreds of compliance and onboarding staff each month, and lexrifyly, a legaltech startup darling with no product, business model, customers or plan but flush with stupid amounts of VC cash, a great deck and an unshakable conviction in the wisdom of goosing its burn-rate by hiring lots of staff.

One evening over canapes Wickliffe Hampton’s Chief Operating Officer Anita Dochter had been bellyaching to her old friend and former trainee, now lexrifyly’s CEO, Cass Mälstrom.

“But we actually need the staff,” she complained. “They actually do productive things for us. But unless we pay your stupid rates, which we cannot afford to do — and give them free fruit, working from home and a soft play area — they won’t stay with us. By contrast, you, right now, don’t need any staff: you simply need to show you are clever, imaginative and on point doing fashionably insane things. This does not require actual staff. If you are not actually hiring anyone, you could be hedging your employment rate risk of not doing so.

As luck would have it, Hunter Barkley was waiting tables that evening and overhead the conversation. He presented them with a pitch book with the check:

For an initial period of three years, Wickliffe would pay its wage bill for its entire operations team in London, controlled for performance, to lexrifyly. In return, lexrifyly would pay its projected wage budget for an equivalent sized-team to Wickliffe Hampton.[3] A firm having a bad year while its competitors feasted had no option but to hike pay to stop flush rivals piratically raiding its meagre stocks of human capital. By the same token, a firm that was knocking the ball out of the park while its competitors floundered, did not need to pay its own staff outsized bonuses. Where were they going to go?

Legend has it, should she ever be asked for a raise, the Vampire Squid’s fearsome GC would theatrically throw open a draw stuffed with unsolicited resumes. “I am sure we’ll find someone to do your job if you’re too good for it.”

Now this only works when the industry is not in the grip of some mania or other. History tells us usually it is: dot-com startups, hedge funds, crypto and private equity have all skewed the market for unremarkable drones in recent times. This is why magic circle firms pay guileless trainees two hundred grand and then have to charge them out at £600 an hour. But I digress.

Expansion

In any case, the option is ugly, whether you are long or short, on either side. Even for a Vampire Squid. Usually, banks were structurally short a rising bid. If rapacious private equity firms or gormless crypto startups were swiping mid-ranking harness bulls from their operations department, banks had little choice but to follow the bid — for replacement hires. They thereby had “duration risk”: current staff would put up with a certain amount of stiff-arming, but there were limits: human capital management desk traders priced staff like fixed rate term debt with a three-month call. New staff would come in at the prevailing astral rates, so HCM hedging strategies were vital.

Enter Barkley’s invention: employment rate swaps promised to change that by tanking lateral movements — which were necessarily highly entropic in that they cost a lot in transaction friction, institutional leakage and so on and which could be avoided by just paying the employees more.


The banks could sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the bother of having to hedge themselves.

Barkley also saw the opportunity to trade the instrument as an abstract benchmark, for which you need not be employed at all. So did banks, unfortunately, and so began the employment rate swap misselling scandal during which banks would separately hedge out their employee risk and then peremptorily terminate the staff member’s employment, leaving her holding a twenty five year out of the money employment rate swap.

The LIEBOR rate was not the only component of an individual swap: each employee would also have a credibility spread over or under the prevailing LIEBOR rate. This was a competence assessment made by human capital analysts if the staff. Mispricing this could lead to staff defections, to it was routinely marked to market and adjusted by way of a 360° credibility appraisal process.

It led to anomalies. HR departments would segment staff according to an internal 5 point scoring metric (a “credibility rating”), and would force rank staff to a curve, lest the banks exposure to employee “alpha” became too concentrated.

Interdepartmental secondments were beset by cheapest to deliver strategies and diversity arbitrage, particularly over quarter end.

Meantime while periodic RIFs were greatly reduced they were not avoided entirely, and now could be handled quantitatively without reference to performance or value as it was baked into the credibility rating. This led to the curious counterintuitive phenomenon that the staff with the highest credibility ratings — ergo the most, well, “pound for pound” expensive — were the first to go. This assisted also in the force ranking process.

“LIEBOR” submission process

They would be like interest rate swaps. A bunch of large employers would submit, daily, how much they would be prepared to pay to hire established categories of worker, to derive some kind of London Inter-Employer Bid-Offer Rate (can we call this LIEBOR?). Then the British Human Capital Managers Association would compile and publish a list of rates. Employers could swap out their fixed costs for a floating rate, thereby hedging employment costs. Employees could do the same, hedging against their intrinsic loyalty discount, and restricting employee moves to genuine changes in role, or idiosyncratic hatred of boss, rather than just the need to rebenchmark periodically.

See also

References

  1. The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%
  2. From the Greek παράνοια, (paranoia). It was also pleasing that it conveyed sentiments of going around in a circle, running on a hamster wheel and so on, all of which Barkley recognised to be fundamental properties of the employment relationship.
  3. This was slightly complicated as it was denominated in crypto and needed to be converted back to Sterling.