Employment derivatives: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit Advanced mobile edit
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{a|myth|{{image|Ironmountain1|jpg|}}}}{{d|Employment derivatives|/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/|n|}}Financial instruments designed to manage the risk of employment variability. First developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, {{author|Hunter Barkley}}.
{{a|myth|{{image|Ironmountain1|jpg|}}}}{{d|Employment derivatives|/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/|n|}}Financial instruments designed to manage the risk of employment variability. First developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, {{author|Hunter Barkley}}.
====Genesis====
====Genesis====
{{Drop|W|hen midway through}} midway through his annual rant about the meaningless of life as viewed through the lens of his income, it struck Barkley an amateur [[fi-fi]] novelist, financial services naturalist and [[tiresome]] windbag, not in that order — that just as his own pay packet was a material, unhedged contingency in his life having little to do with how good he was at it (his work, or life for that matter), so too was everyone else’s.  
{{Drop|W|hen midway through}} midway through his annual rant about the meaningless of life as viewed through the lens of his income, Hunter Barkley had an epiphany. For sure, his own pay packet was a material, unhedged contingency in his life. The perpetual disappointment that it rained upon his sorry existence had, he knew, little to do with how good he was at it (work, or existence for that matter). He knew, too, that his experience was common to the great dreary sweep of humankind as myopically it crawled across the clanking gears of the global machine.  


This included, at far greater scale, employers. Barkley believed himself, rightly, to be short an ugly [[option]] to the Man. But by the same, token so too was the Man short an option to the tide of corporate hysteria that regularly floods the market.  
But that was not the revelation. It was this: just as Barkley and the great collected horde of mortgaged servants were severally at the whim of wanton Gods — so too, necessarily, was an employer who stood the other side of the trade, only at far greater scale. Businesses — particularly ''boring'' businesses — were at the mercy of the fickle tides of hysteria that regularly flood the market.


For no other reason than deluded euphoria, a boring employer like a bank would see an annual ''variance'' in its total wage bill, even before accounting for ''changes'' in in its staff, in the ''billions'' of dollars.<ref>The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%</ref>
A turgid employer of multitudes — a good-sized bank, for example — was in a constant war to prevent essentially pedestrian operations personnel from being lured by exciting but basically stupid enterprises chasing the latest techno-craze. Just stemming this outflow might inflate its total wage bill by ''billions'' of dollars.<ref>The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%</ref> As the inflated expectations of the latest technology then predictably foundered the bank would find itself spoilt for choice in a buyers’ market, and its wage bill would collapse.


This volatility bore no relation to its own performance, none to its employees’, and a lot with how ''other'' employers were doing in adjacent, more exciting sectors.  
In any case this volatility bore little relation to the bank’s own performance, none at all to its employees’. It was a simple measure of background market euphoria. Barkley reasoned that different types of firm were “long” or “short” this babbling hysteria, which he labelled ''π'',<ref>From the Greek παράνοια, (''paranoia''). It was also pleasing that π conveys circularity, running on a hamster wheel and so on, all of which Barkley recognised to be fundamental properties of the employment relationship.</ref>  at different points in the hype cycle.  


Barkley reasoned that different types of firm were “long” or “short” this babbling hysteria, which he labelled ''π'',<ref>From the Greek παράνοια, (''paranoia''). It was also pleasing that π conveys circularity, running on a hamster wheel and so on, all of which Barkley recognised to be fundamental properties of the employment relationship.</ref> at different points in the hype cycle.
At its onset, “trad-fi”, “bricks-and-mortar” firms were short, and delusional start-ups long, ''π''. As the lunacy levelled off, reality set in and employment relations [[Mean reversion|reverted to mean]], the ''π'' curve would flatten and then eventually invert. If one could only match off long and a short exposures, Barkley realised, firms on either side of the bid could hedge their exposure to π.   


At its onset, “legacy”, “bricks-and-mortar”, “trad-fi” firms were typically short ''π'' and fantastical start-ups long. As the lunacy tailed off, reality set in and employment relations [[Mean reversion|reverted to mean]], the ''π'' curve would flatten and then invert.  
In one of those cruel ironies to whose martial cadence our lives keep time, before he could figure out a way of monetising his idea, Barkley was laid off and, shortly afterwards, imprisoned for manipulating [[LIBOR]].


If one could only match off a long and a short firm, Barkley reasoned, each could hedge its exposure to changes in π. 
On release, he was obliged to find work wiping tables by night as he worked on his [[Fi-Fi]] novels and developed his derivative ideas.
 
But how to measure π?
 
[[Human resources|Human capital management]] trading staff were apt to talk about “benchmarking”, as if there were some indexed rate.
 
''Perhaps there ''should'' be a rate'', he thought. The variance was easy enough to calculate, but ''knowing'' about it was a different thing to ''managing'' it. Instinctively, he knew there was something in this idea but could not figure out a way of monetising it.
 
In one of those cruel ironies to whose martial cadence our lives keep time, Barkley was laid off and, shortly afterwards imprisoned for manipulating [[LIBOR]]. On release, he was obliged to find work wiping tables by night as he worked on his [[Fi-Fi]] novels and developed his derivative ideas.


==== The first [[employment rate swap]] ====
==== The first [[employment rate swap]] ====
{{Drop|B|arkley’s fortunes would}} change following a chance encounter in an upscale cocktail bar in West London.  
{{Drop|B|arkley’s fortunes would}} change following a chance encounter in an upscale cocktail bar in West London. As she neared her [[Schwarzschild radius of alcohol consumption|gin horizon]], HR manager Anita Dochter, was bellyaching to her old pal and erstwhile colleague [[Cass Mälstrom]], about the unstaunchable stream of defections from her firm, a sleepy mid-market broker headquartered in Peterborough.  
 
As she neared her [[Schwarzschild radius of alcohol consumption|gin horizon]], Anita Dochter, a middle manager in compliance at [[Wickliffe Hampton Asset Management|Wickliffe Hampton]]  bellyached to her old pal and erstwhile colleague [[Cass Mälstrom]]
 
At the time, [[Wickliffe Hampton]] — a sleepy mid-market broker — was losing hundreds of compliance and onboarding staff each month to venture capital-funded dot-com start-ups. [[Mälstrom]] was just one. She was now CIO of legaltech darling [[lexrifyly]]


[[lexrifyly]] had no product to speak of, no business model, customers or plan but was flush with stupid amounts of cash, a great [[Microsoft PowerPoint|deck]] and an unshakable conviction in the wisdom of goosing its burn-rate by overpaying for bums it didn’t need on seats it didn’t have.  
At the time the firm was haemorrhaging hundreds of compliance and onboarding staff each month to venture capital-funded dot-com start-ups. Mälstrom herself had been plucked from the firm’s client money compliance programme to be [[Co-head|Co-deputy CIO]] of legaltech darling [[lexrifyly]] not three months earlier. [[lexrifyly]] had no product to speak of, no business model, customers or plan but was flush with stupid amounts of cash, a great [[Microsoft PowerPoint|deck]] and an unshakable conviction in goosing its burn-rate by overpaying for bums it didn’t need on seats it didn’t yet have.


“But,” complained Dochter, “we actually ''need'' our people. They actually do productive things for us. You know: [[MIS]] reports. Operational [[deep dive]]s. [[Netting]] audits .But unless we pay ''your'' stupid rates for them, which we cannot afford to do —” at this point she fell off her stool briefly — “and give them free fruit, unlimited working from home and a soft play area — they won’t stay with us. But, ''you'',” she hissed, clambering back up and jabbing [[Cass Mälstrom|Mälstrom]] on the lapel, “right now, ''you'' don’t need ''any goddamn'' staff: you just need to show your investors you are clever, imaginative and on point doing fashionably insane things. That does not take actual staff. So stop taking mine.”   
“But,” complained Dochter, “we actually ''need'' our people. They actually do productive things for us. You know: [[MIS]] reports. Operational [[deep dive]]s. [[Netting]] audits. But unless we pay ''your'' stupid rates for them, which we cannot afford to do —” at this point she fell off her stool briefly — “and give them free fruit, unlimited working from home and a soft play area — they won’t stay with us. But, ''you'',” she hissed, clambering back up and jabbing [[Cass Mälstrom|Mälstrom]] on the lapel, “right now, ''you'' don’t need ''any goddamn'' staff: you just need to show your investors you are clever, imaginative and on point doing fashionably insane things. That does not take actual staff. So stop taking ours.”   


As luck would have it, Barkley was attending their table that evening. He presented them with the check and some after dinner mints. Barkley cleared his throat. And dropped a document on the table.
As luck would have it, Barkley was attending their table that evening. As he presented them with the check and some after dinner mints Barkley cleared his throat and dropped a document on the table.


“Forgive me for imposing, but I could not help overhearing. If you are not actually hiring anyone, why not hedge your employment rate risk to someone who is?”
“Forgive me for imposing, but I could not help overhearing. If you are not actually hiring anyone, why not hedge your employment rate risk to someone who is?”
Line 40: Line 28:
Dochter fell off her stool again.  
Dochter fell off her stool again.  


 
Mälstrom indicated the booklet. “What’s this?”  
Mälstrom indicated the booklet .“What’s this?”


“[[NDA]]. Call me.”
“[[NDA]]. Call me.”


So was the first “[[employment rate swap]]” conceived.  
So was the first “[[employment rate swap]]” conceived. For an initial period of three years, Wickliffe would pay its entire operations wage bill, controlled for performance, to lexrifyly. In return, lexrifyly would pay its absurd, grossly inflated but as yet unallocated wage budget for an equivalent sized-team — there was no such team, of course: this was exactly the point — to Wickliffe Hampton.<ref>This was slightly complicated as it was denominated in [[crypto]] and needed to be converted back to Sterling.  </ref>  
 
For an initial period of three years, Wickliffe would pay its entire operations wage bill, controlled for performance, to lexrifyly. In return, lexrifyly would pay its absurd, grossly inflated but actually unallocated wage budget for an equivalent sized-team — there was no such team; this was exactly the point — to Wickliffe Hampton.<ref>This was slightly complicated as it was denominated in [[crypto]] and needed to be converted back to Sterling.  </ref>


This way, Wickliffe Hampton had the cash required to preemptively bid back restless staff, and lexrifyly could guilelessly piss its investors cash up a wall without troubling the operating resiliency of the banking sector, or needing an HR department.   
This way, Wickliffe Hampton had the cash required to preemptively bid back restless staff, and lexrifyly could, in time-honoured fashion, guilelessly piddle its investors’ cash up a wall without troubling the operating resiliency of the banking sector, or for that matter, needing an [[Human resources|HR department]].   


If this seemed like a bad trade for lexrifyly, (a) it didn’t care: what was money? and (b) ther economics would change markedly should there be a tech winter with widescale redundancies and hiring freezes.  And ironically, at that point, it wold have sensible amount of cash coming in from Wickliffe Hampton that it could use to hire some people.  
If this seemed like a bad trade for lexrifyly, but in actuality it was not. Firstly, it didn’t care: what was money? Secondly, the economics would change markedly upon the onset of a more hawkish monetary policy, the dissipation of hysteria or any of the other things that could precipitate a tech winter, and the widescale redundancies and hiring freezes that was sure to follow it.  And ironically, at that point, a counterparty short ''π'' in an ERS would have sensible amount of cash coming in it could use to hire some people.  


It was easy enough to quantify Wickliffe Hampton’s presumptive wage bill: it was more or less static. But what about lexrifyly’s fantastical aspirations? How to gauge those in real time? And could not lexrifyly game this very easily, by just pretending its wage bill was lower?  
There remained a problem: it was easy enough to quantify a bank’s presumptive wage bill (once it was controlled for hysteria) as it was more or less static. But what about the ever-changing hypothetical wage bill of a startup? How to gauge that in real time? And could not a startup not game this very easily, by just pretending its actual preparedness to pay stupid money was lower that it really was?  
    
    
====The “LIEBOR” submission process====
====The “LIEBOR” submission process====
{{Drop|W|hat was needed}}, Barkley reasoned, was an observable, objective measure of startup insanity, ''π''. He had just the means for achieving it. Under the auspices of the British Human Capital Managers’ Association (BHCMA) a committee of fashionable startups would meet each afternoon in a WeWork in Shoreditch for an kombucha martini and to state publicly, in front of a live panel of venture capitalists, how much they would be prepared to pay an underperforming settlements and reconciliations specialist to join them and drive customer engagement.   
{{Drop|W|hat was needed}}, Barkley reasoned, was an observable, objective measure of startup insanity, ''π''. He had just the means for achieving it. Under the auspices of the British Human Capital Managers’ Association (BHCMA) a committee of fashionable startups would meet each afternoon in a WeWork in Shoreditch for an kombucha martini and to state publicly, in front of a live panel of venture capitalists, how much they would be prepared to pay an underperforming settlements and reconciliations specialist to join them and drive customer engagement.   


The BHCMA would trim the top and bottom estimates, average the remainder and compile and publish the trimmed arithmetic mean rate as the [[London Inter-Employer Basic Offered Rate]] ([[LIEBOR]]). LIEBOR quickly become the ''de facto''  measure of  ''π'' and was soon factored into the “floating” leg of [[employment rate swap]]<nowiki/>s as standard.  
The BHCMA would trim the top and bottom estimates, average the remainder and compile and publish the trimmed arithmetic mean rate as the [[London Inter-Employer Basic Offered Rate]] ([[LIEBOR]]). LIEBOR quickly become the ''de facto''  measure of  ''π'' and was soon factored into the “floating” leg of [[employment rate swap]]<nowiki/>s as standard.


The banks could even sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the banks the bother of having to hedge themselves. By the same token employees could hedge away their intrinsic loyalty discount, and restricting their need to find new jobs to genuine changes in role or idiosyncratic hatred of their bosses. But there was no need to simply “benchmark” themselves periodically any more.
The banks could even sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the banks the bother of having to hedge themselves. By the same token employees could hedge away their intrinsic loyalty discount, and restricting their need to find new jobs to genuine changes in role or idiosyncratic hatred of their bosses. But there was no need to simply “benchmark” themselves periodically any more.

Revision as of 11:42, 15 April 2024

Myths and legends of the market
The JC’s guide to the foundational mythology of the markets.™
Ironmountain1.jpg
Index: Click to expand:

Comments? Questions? Suggestions? Requests? Insults? We’d love to 📧 hear from you.
Sign up for our newsletter.

Employment derivatives
/ɪmˈplɔɪmənt dɪˈrɪvətɪvz/ (n.)
Financial instruments designed to manage the risk of employment variability. First developed in the early part of this millennium by derivatives pioneer and perennial boiler of pots, Hunter Barkley.

Genesis

When midway through midway through his annual rant about the meaningless of life as viewed through the lens of his income, Hunter Barkley had an epiphany. For sure, his own pay packet was a material, unhedged contingency in his life. The perpetual disappointment that it rained upon his sorry existence had, he knew, little to do with how good he was at it (work, or existence for that matter). He knew, too, that his experience was common to the great dreary sweep of humankind as myopically it crawled across the clanking gears of the global machine.

But that was not the revelation. It was this: just as Barkley and the great collected horde of mortgaged servants were severally at the whim of wanton Gods — so too, necessarily, was an employer who stood the other side of the trade, only at far greater scale. Businesses — particularly boring businesses — were at the mercy of the fickle tides of hysteria that regularly flood the market.

A turgid employer of multitudes — a good-sized bank, for example — was in a constant war to prevent essentially pedestrian operations personnel from being lured by exciting but basically stupid enterprises chasing the latest techno-craze. Just stemming this outflow might inflate its total wage bill by billions of dollars.[1] As the inflated expectations of the latest technology then predictably foundered the bank would find itself spoilt for choice in a buyers’ market, and its wage bill would collapse.

In any case this volatility bore little relation to the bank’s own performance, none at all to its employees’. It was a simple measure of background market euphoria. Barkley reasoned that different types of firm were “long” or “short” this babbling hysteria, which he labelled π,[2] at different points in the hype cycle.

At its onset, “trad-fi”, “bricks-and-mortar” firms were short, and delusional start-ups long, π. As the lunacy levelled off, reality set in and employment relations reverted to mean, the π curve would flatten and then eventually invert. If one could only match off long and a short exposures, Barkley realised, firms on either side of the bid could hedge their exposure to π.

In one of those cruel ironies to whose martial cadence our lives keep time, before he could figure out a way of monetising his idea, Barkley was laid off and, shortly afterwards, imprisoned for manipulating LIBOR.

On release, he was obliged to find work wiping tables by night as he worked on his Fi-Fi novels and developed his derivative ideas.

The first employment rate swap

Barkley’s fortunes would change following a chance encounter in an upscale cocktail bar in West London. As she neared her gin horizon, HR manager Anita Dochter, was bellyaching to her old pal and erstwhile colleague Cass Mälstrom, about the unstaunchable stream of defections from her firm, a sleepy mid-market broker headquartered in Peterborough.

At the time the firm was haemorrhaging hundreds of compliance and onboarding staff each month to venture capital-funded dot-com start-ups. Mälstrom herself had been plucked from the firm’s client money compliance programme to be Co-deputy CIO of legaltech darling lexrifyly not three months earlier. lexrifyly had no product to speak of, no business model, customers or plan but was flush with stupid amounts of cash, a great deck and an unshakable conviction in goosing its burn-rate by overpaying for bums it didn’t need on seats it didn’t yet have.

“But,” complained Dochter, “we actually need our people. They actually do productive things for us. You know: MIS reports. Operational deep dives. Netting audits. But unless we pay your stupid rates for them, which we cannot afford to do —” at this point she fell off her stool briefly — “and give them free fruit, unlimited working from home and a soft play area — they won’t stay with us. But, you,” she hissed, clambering back up and jabbing Mälstrom on the lapel, “right now, you don’t need any goddamn staff: you just need to show your investors you are clever, imaginative and on point doing fashionably insane things. That does not take actual staff. So stop taking ours.”

As luck would have it, Barkley was attending their table that evening. As he presented them with the check and some after dinner mints Barkley cleared his throat and dropped a document on the table.

“Forgive me for imposing, but I could not help overhearing. If you are not actually hiring anyone, why not hedge your employment rate risk to someone who is?”

Dochter fell off her stool again.

Mälstrom indicated the booklet. “What’s this?”

NDA. Call me.”

So was the first “employment rate swap” conceived. For an initial period of three years, Wickliffe would pay its entire operations wage bill, controlled for performance, to lexrifyly. In return, lexrifyly would pay its absurd, grossly inflated but as yet unallocated wage budget for an equivalent sized-team — there was no such team, of course: this was exactly the point — to Wickliffe Hampton.[3]

This way, Wickliffe Hampton had the cash required to preemptively bid back restless staff, and lexrifyly could, in time-honoured fashion, guilelessly piddle its investors’ cash up a wall without troubling the operating resiliency of the banking sector, or for that matter, needing an HR department.

If this seemed like a bad trade for lexrifyly, but in actuality it was not. Firstly, it didn’t care: what was money? Secondly, the economics would change markedly upon the onset of a more hawkish monetary policy, the dissipation of hysteria or any of the other things that could precipitate a tech winter, and the widescale redundancies and hiring freezes that was sure to follow it. And ironically, at that point, a counterparty short π in an ERS would have sensible amount of cash coming in it could use to hire some people.

There remained a problem: it was easy enough to quantify a bank’s presumptive wage bill (once it was controlled for hysteria) as it was more or less static. But what about the ever-changing hypothetical wage bill of a startup? How to gauge that in real time? And could not a startup not game this very easily, by just pretending its actual preparedness to pay stupid money was lower that it really was?

The “LIEBOR” submission process

What was needed, Barkley reasoned, was an observable, objective measure of startup insanity, π. He had just the means for achieving it. Under the auspices of the British Human Capital Managers’ Association (BHCMA) a committee of fashionable startups would meet each afternoon in a WeWork in Shoreditch for an kombucha martini and to state publicly, in front of a live panel of venture capitalists, how much they would be prepared to pay an underperforming settlements and reconciliations specialist to join them and drive customer engagement.

The BHCMA would trim the top and bottom estimates, average the remainder and compile and publish the trimmed arithmetic mean rate as the London Inter-Employer Basic Offered Rate (LIEBOR). LIEBOR quickly become the de facto measure of π and was soon factored into the “floating” leg of employment rate swaps as standard.

The banks could even sell these derivatives directly to employees, saving the banks the bother of having to hedge themselves. By the same token employees could hedge away their intrinsic loyalty discount, and restricting their need to find new jobs to genuine changes in role or idiosyncratic hatred of their bosses. But there was no need to simply “benchmark” themselves periodically any more.

Credibility spread

LIEBOR was not the only component of an individual swap: each employee would also have a performance-related “credibility spread” over (or under) the prevailing LIEBOR rate. This was a competence assessment made by human capital analysts. Mispricing this could lead to staff defections, to it was routinely marked to market and adjusted by way of a 360° credibility appraisal process.

For portfolio transactions (like the first ERS, which was departmental-wide) analysts would assign a weighted average credibility spread. This could yield occasional anomalies. Though HR departments assiduously segmented staff according to an internal 5 point scoring metric (a “credibility rating”), and would force rank staff to a given curve there remained risks that exposure to employee “alpha” could be mispriced or too overly concentrated.

Interdepartmental secondments were beset by credibility rating and diversity arbitrage and cheapest to deliver scandals especially over quarter end.

Meantime, while periodic RIFs were greatly reduced they were not eradicated entirely, but now could be handled quantitatively without reference to individual performance or value — as that was baked into one’s credibility rating.

This led to the curious phenomenon of staff with the highest credibility ratings — ergo those who were, “pound for pound”, most expensive — being the first to go. This was of a piece with the theory that firms actively discouraged excellent employees, preferring those to meatheaded to do anything rash like using initiative.

Expansion

Barkley also saw the opportunity to trade the instrument as an abstract benchmark, for which one did not need exposure to the employment market at all. Thus was made possible by offsetting nature of ERS transactions. You needed to be neither long or short actual staff but could trade directionally on abstract π.

This led to a proliferation of exotic ERS products, many with me practical utility and unintuitive consequences. So began the sad chronicle of employment rate swap mis-selling. In this dark episode banks would separately hedge out their employee’s π risk, to the employee herself[4]and then peremptorily lay the employee off, leaving her holding a twenty five year out of the money employment rate swap. And badly exposed should crypto go tits up.

See also

References

  1. The maths was like so: assume 40,000 people at an average total compensation of about $300,000, with a ratio of discretionary to fixed of between 20% and 50%
  2. From the Greek παράνοια, (paranoia). It was also pleasing that π conveys circularity, running on a hamster wheel and so on, all of which Barkley recognised to be fundamental properties of the employment relationship.
  3. This was slightly complicated as it was denominated in crypto and needed to be converted back to Sterling.  
  4. Self-referencing employment derivatives are now not permitted in many jurisdictions, and attract penalty risk weighing in the UK.