Rent-seeking: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 28: Line 28:
But there is a paradox here: If your [[legaltech]] solution costs you something like two: that is, it continues to require costs and resources such that two represents a fair margin on work you continue to do, then ''this is not legaltech but something else.'' It may well be deft process-reengineering coupled with [[outsourcing]]<ref>[[Outsourcing]] has its own hidden costs and shortcomings, of course.</ref> —  but that is ''not'' [[legaltech]]. That is [[Management consultant|''management consultancy'']].  
But there is a paradox here: If your [[legaltech]] solution costs you something like two: that is, it continues to require costs and resources such that two represents a fair margin on work you continue to do, then ''this is not legaltech but something else.'' It may well be deft process-reengineering coupled with [[outsourcing]]<ref>[[Outsourcing]] has its own hidden costs and shortcomings, of course.</ref> —  but that is ''not'' [[legaltech]]. That is [[Management consultant|''management consultancy'']].  


If your solution really is legaltech: if the work needed to remove your ongoing cost of ten is achieved upon implementation done, there is no-longer an ongoing cost of ten. My question is now: what on earth am I paying this one for? .
If your solution really is legaltech: if the work needed to remove your ongoing cost of ten is achieved upon implementation done then, once I have paid for its implementation, why should I pay an ongoing marginal cost per unit?  


If the legaltech solution does not consume ongoing resources and costs, then once I have paid for its implementation, why should I pay an ongoing marginal cost per unit? The machine is solving my problem for nothing: the ongoing cost its vendor seeks is pure rent extraction.
My problem is solved. There is no longer an ongoing cost of ten. The machine costs nothing to operate. My question is now: what on earth am I paying this ongoing running cost ''for''? {{sa}}
 
 
{{sa}}
*[[ClauseHub: theory]]
*[[ClauseHub: theory]]
*[[Reg tech]]
*[[Reg tech]]

Revision as of 10:03, 12 October 2022

Rent Way Past Due. (von Sachsen-Rampton, 1962)
In which the curmudgeonly old sod puts the world to rights.
Index — Click ᐅ to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

Rent-seeking
/rɛnt ˈsiːkɪŋ/ (n.)

The extraction of payment by one (a “rentier” or in the JC’s own phrase, a “rentsmith”) from those who pass by, for the simple privilege of crossing one’s turf, whether they are transgressing one’s real property — that’s the classic notion of “rent” — personal property — unusual, but renting a car, or skis — or intellectual property — and this is where the real monkey business happens.

Rent-seeking only becomes problematic where there are conditions of monopoly. Since few landlords or rental companies have monopoly positions, it doesn’t tend to present a problem here. Since intellectual property is more or less a state-sanctioned form of monopoly, this is where the problems arise.

For such an important concept — it is really hard to understand our piebald world without it — it is very hard to pin down.

It comes in many guises:

  • Physical property: you know, literal rent-seeking
  • Intellectual property: Rather than using the fruits of your blood, toil, tears and sweat you use antediluvian[1] intellectual property rules to gouge everyone else. In this way Mick Jagger and Keith Richards can extract tens of millions over 60 years from 15 minutes of work — in Richards’ case, while, on his own account, he was asleep — composing Satisfaction.
  • Franchising: Taking an idea or a business model someone else has invented — McDonald’s is the best example — and paying them a franchise fee to operate it. Here is double rent-seeking: the franchisee pays the franchisor, and the customer pays the franchisee.
  • Software as a service: The simple answer to the question why is reg tech so disappointing? — is that tech businesses can’t make money if all they get paid for is writing software. This would be like Mick Jagger only getting paid for fifteen minutes’ work — where is the logic, or the justice in that?[2]
  • Regulatory rent-seeking: A regulatory fine for some impermissible behaviour which, while significant, pales into insignificance with the value accrued to the miscreant who carries out the behaviour, such that it suits both of them to carry on with the activity. Where the time don’t match the crime.

Legal eagles as rent-seekers

Rent-seeking is at the heart of the agency problem. An agent seeks to advance her principal’s interests but, above all, she wants to remain and agent, so she can be paid. If her principal’s best interests are served by doing away with her agency, you can be sure she will struggle to voice this proposition to her client.

Take the contract negotiation process: it features a bunch of stakeholders who like being involved in it, who want to stay involved in it, even though, by the lights of the new model, they don’t add any value. Their primary purpose is to extract rent. They have structured themselves into the architecture of their organisations and the market. They don’t want any “solution” which prevents them continuing to extract rent. It is the agency problem, par excellence.

This is what is so interesting about OneNDA. It may be small and seemingly insignificant in its subject matter, but it strikes the rent extraction problem at its root. Rather than changing the mode of “service delivery” (for which, read, “mode of rent extraction”) or automating, accelerating or otherwise making more efficient the process of extracting rent, OneNDA banishes rent altogether. Business owners can fill out a form, and sign it, by themselves. No agents required.

There has been much thought leadership on the subject of reforming contracting processes, but all of it takes as read that some rent extraction must take place. The OneNDA is different. The forces of rent extraction are deep, and persistent, and powerful, and do not expect them to lay down in front of a shepherd-boy with a sling the way Goliath did.

Legaltech as a rent-extraction machine

We talk about this elsewhere, but herein is the fundamental problem with legaltech. Legaltech addresses inefficiencies which manifest themselves as negative annuities: ongoing costs and resource drains for quotidian tasks with minimal value. It is, therefore, predicated on the vendor earning not just a profit, but an annuity. The thought process is this: if customers have an ongoing cost of ten, they will be prepared to pay me an ongoing cost of two to remove it. Mathematically, unimpeachable logic.

But there is a paradox here: If your legaltech solution costs you something like two: that is, it continues to require costs and resources such that two represents a fair margin on work you continue to do, then this is not legaltech but something else. It may well be deft process-reengineering coupled with outsourcing[3] — but that is not legaltech. That is management consultancy.

If your solution really is legaltech: if the work needed to remove your ongoing cost of ten is achieved upon implementation done then, once I have paid for its implementation, why should I pay an ongoing marginal cost per unit?

My problem is solved. There is no longer an ongoing cost of ten. The machine costs nothing to operate. My question is now: what on earth am I paying this ongoing running cost for? ==See also==

References

  1. Lawrence Lessig’s Code: Version 2.0 is a compulsory read.
  2. Irony alert.
  3. Outsourcing has its own hidden costs and shortcomings, of course.