Template:M intro isda Party A and Party B: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{quote|{{D|Bilateral|/ˌbaɪˈlætᵊrᵊl/|adj}}Having, or relating to, two sides; affecting both sides equally.}}
{{quote|{{D|Bilateral|/ˌbaɪˈlætᵊrᵊl/|adj}}Having, or relating to, two sides; affecting both sides equally.}}


{{smallcaps|[[Party A and Party B - ISDA Provision|In this episode]]}} of the JC’s series of deep explorations of superficial things in the [[ISDA]] metaverse, we consider the “bilateral” nature of the {{isdama}} and its curious designators: “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”, and that curious descriptor of both of them: “[[counterparty]]”.  
{{smallcaps|[[Party A and Party B - ISDA Provision|In this episode]]}} the JC considers the “bilateral” nature of the {{isdama}}, why swap participants are called “[[counterparty|counterparties]]” what this confusing “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}” business is all about.  


These set the ISDA apart; give it a sort of otherworldly aloofness; a sense almost of social justice. Other banking and broking transactions use labels which help you orient who, in the [[power structure]], is who: a loan has a “Lender” (always the bank) and “Borrower” always the punter. A brokerage has “Broker” (master) and “Customer” (servant).  
These labels set the ISDA apart from its fellow [[finance contract]]<nowiki/>s. They give it a sort of otherworldly aloofness; a sense of social justice. Other banking and broking transactions use labels which help you orient who, in the [[power structure]], is who: a loan has a “[[Lender]]” (always the bank) and “[[Borrower]]” always the punter. A brokerage has “[[Broker]]” (master) and “[[Customer]]” (servant).<ref>Okay I know ''theoretically'' it is the other way around, but it isn’t, is it? You are hooked up to the great battery grid, just like everyone else. Admit it.</ref>


But not the {{isdama}}. From the outside its framers — the [[First Men]] — opted for the more gnomic, interchangeable “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.
But not the {{isdama}}. From the outside its framers — the [[First Men]] — opted for the more gnomic, interchangeable and ''equal designators'' “{{isdaprov|Party A}}” and “{{isdaprov|Party B}}”.


Why? Well, we learn it from our first encounter of an ISDA Schedule. ''[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|Bilaterality]]''.
Why? Well, we learn it from our first encounter of an ISDA Schedule. ''[[The bilaterality, or not, of the ISDA|Bilaterality]]''.
Line 12: Line 12:
{{smallcaps|A belief in}} even-handedness gripped the ones whose [[deep magic]] forged the runes from which the [[First Swap]] was born.  
{{smallcaps|A belief in}} even-handedness gripped the ones whose [[deep magic]] forged the runes from which the [[First Swap]] was born.  


For most finance contracts imply some sort of dominance and subservience: a large institutional “have” indulging a small commercial “have-not” with debt finance for the privilege of which the larger “have” extracts excruciating covenants and enjoys a preferred place in the queue for repayment among the have-not’s many scrapping creditors.
Where most finance contracts imply some sort of dominance and subservience.  A large institutional “have” indulges a small commercial “have-not” with debt finance, for which privilege the bank extracts excruciating covenants and enjoys a preferred place in the queue for repayment among the customer’s many scrapping creditors.


But [[swaps]], as the [[First Men]] saw them, are not like that.  
But [[swaps]], as the [[First Men]] saw them, are not like that.  


“A swap contract,” they intoned, “is an exchange among peers. It is an equal-opportunity sort of thing; Biblically righteous in that, under its awnings, one be neither lender nor borrower, but an honest rival for the favour of the Lady Fortune, however capricious may she be.  
“A swap contract,” they intoned, “is an exchange among peers. It is an equal-opportunity sort of thing; Biblically righteous in that, under its awnings, one be neither lender nor borrower, but an honest rival for the favour of the Lady Fortune, however capricious may she be.


“We are equals. Rivals. ''Counterparties''”. Covenants, privileges of credit support and so on may flow either way. They may flow ''both'' ways. In our time of [[regulatory margin]], they usually do.
“Thus, we are equals. Rivals. ''Counterparties''”.  


And, to be sure, swaps ''are'' different from loans and brokerage arrangements. They start off “at market” where all is square. Either party may be long or short, fixed or floating. At the moment the trade is struck, the world infused with glorious ''possibility''. One fellow’s fortunes may rise or fall relative to the other’s and, as a result, she may ''owe'' (“[[out-of-the-money]]”) or ''be owed'' (“[[in-the-money]]”). And swaps, too, are professional instruments. Moms and pops, [[Belgian dentist]]s and the like may take loans and buy bonds, but they don’t, and never have, entered {{isdama}}s.<ref>They may trade [[contracts for difference]] and make spread bets with brokers, but these are standardised, smaller contracts.</ref>
Covenants, privileges of credit support and so on may, thereby, flow either way. They may flow ''both'' ways. In our time of [[regulatory margin]], they usually do.


Now the {{isdama}} ''itself'' never uses the terms “Party A” or “Party B”. Being genuinely bilateral, it never has to. Being arbitrary assignations at trade level the labels only get a mention once the symmetry breaks down in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} and in {{isdaprov|Confirmation}}s, to be clear who is who on a given trade: who is paying the fixed rate and who the floating; which thresholds, maxima, minima, covenants, details, agents and terms apply to which counterparty. This much is necessarily different. Nothing beyond: the {{isdama}} assumes you already know who is who, having agreed it in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}}.
And, to be sure, swaps ''are'' different from loans and brokerage arrangements. They start off “at market”, where all is square. Either party may be long or short, fixed or floating: at the moment the trade is struck, the world infused with glorious possibility.  


So we agree: for this relationship we will call you “Party B”, and me “Party A”.  
One fellow’s fortunes may rise or fall relative to the other’s and, as a result, she may ''owe'' (in the vernacular, be “[[out-of-the-money]]”) or ''be owed'' (“[[in-the-money]]”). And swaps, too, are professional instruments. Moms and pops, [[Belgian dentist]]s and the like may take loans and buy bonds, but they don’t, and never have, entered {{isdama}}s.<ref>They may trade [[contracts for difference]] and make spread bets with brokers, but these are standardised, smaller contracts.</ref>


These colourless and generic terms hark from a time where, we presume, the idea of “find and replace all” in an electronic document seemed some kind of devilish black magic. Some kind of [[Tipp-Ex]]-denying subterfuge.  
Curiously, the pre-printed {{isdama}} itself never uses the expressions “Party A” or “Party B”. [[2002 ISDA wikitext|Have a look, if you don’t believe me]]. Being genuinely bilateral, it never has to. Being arbitrary assignations at trade level, party-specific labels only get a mention once the symmetry breaks down. That happens in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}} and in {{isdaprov|Confirmation}}s, to be clear who is who on a given trade, or for a given bespoke convenant: who pays the [[fixed rate]] and who the [[Floating rate|floating]]; which thresholds, maxima, minima, covenants, details, agents and terms apply to which counterparty. This much is necessarily different. Nothing beyond: the {{isdama}} assumes you already know who is who, having agreed it in the {{isdaprov|Schedule}}.


But anyway. These generic labels still lead to practical difficulties. A [[dealer]] with ten thousand counterparties in its portfolio wants to be “Party A” every time, just for peace of mind and literary continuity when perusing its collection of Schedules, as we know [[dealer]]s on occasion are minded to do.<ref>They are not.</ref> If, here and there, a dealer must be “Party B”, this can lead to anxious moments should one misread such a Schedule and infer its infinite [[IM]] {{csaprov|Threshold}} applies to the other guy, when really, as it ought, it applies to you. Frights like this are, in their way, quite energising.
So we agree: for this swap trading relationship we will call you “Party B”, and me “Party A”. Beyond these colourless labels, we are equal. These generic terms hark from a time where the idea of “find and replace all” in an electronic document seemed like [[Tipp-Ex]]-denying, devilish magic.  
You quickly get over them when you realise it is your error of construal, not the negotiator’s of articulation.  


Less energising are actual errors: as a group, [[negotiator]]s are redoubtable, admirable creatures but, like all of us fallible and prone to oversight: they may, by lowly force of habit, forget to invert the “Party” labels when inserting the boilerplate {{isdaprov|PPF Event}} rider for that one time in a thousand when the firm is not “Party A”. It is easily done, and just the sort of thing a [[four-eyes check]] will also miss: If it does, no-one will never know — ''unless and until it is too late''.
But anyway. Being ''so'' generic, the “Party A” and “Party B” labels still lead to practical difficulties: a [[dealer]] with thirty thousand counterparties wants to be “Party A” every time, just for peace of mind and literary continuity when perusing its collection of Schedules, as we know [[dealer]]s on occasion are minded to do.<ref>They are not.</ref> If, here and there, a dealer must be “Party B”, this can lead to anxious moments should one misread one such Schedule and conclude the carefully-argued infinite [[IM]] {{csaprov|Threshold}} applies to the other guy when really, as it ought, it applies to you.


But there is a better objection: for all our automatic protestations to the contrary, the ISDA is not ''really'' a bilateral contract, and it ''is'' often a financing contract, in economic effect even if not in formal structure. Where there is a customer gaining exposure to a risk and a dealer providing delta-hedged exposure to that risk, a swap is a sort of “synthetic loan”.
Frights like this are, in their way, quite energising.
 
==== “BINO” — bilateral in name only ====
{{Smallcaps|But there is}} a better objection: for all our automatic protestations to the contrary, the ISDA is not ''really'' a bilateral contract. It ''is'' often a financing contract, in economic effect even if not in formal structure. Where one side is a customer gaining exposure to a market risk and the other wise is a dealer providing [[Delta hedge|delta-hedged]] exposure to that risk, a swap is a sort of “[[synthetic loan]]”.


This thought grew and grew and now there is a [[A swap as a loan|whole new article about it]].
This thought grew and grew and now there is a [[A swap as a loan|whole new article about it]].
====“BINO” — bilateral in name only====
 
{{smallcaps|But except for}} that a class of [[Inter-dealer|inter-dealer]] swap relationships, {{isdama}}s are “bilateral” only really in ''name'': one party — the [[swap dealer]], provides exposures to another, the customer, who consumes them. The customer provides the impulse to trade; the customer elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The [[dealer]] hedges, calculates values and is burdened with additional [[regulatory capital]] charges if it doesn’t get its [[close-out netting]] right.
But except for that a class of [[Inter-dealer|inter-dealer]] swap relationships, {{isdama}}s are “bilateral” only really in ''name'': one party — the [[swap dealer]], provides exposures to another, the customer, who consumes them. The customer provides the impulse to trade; the customer elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The [[dealer]] hedges, calculates values and is burdened with additional [[regulatory capital]] charges if it doesn’t get its [[close-out netting]] right. The customer punts.


This has led to two kinds of bother: first, a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since [[swap dealer]]s set up their templates to assume ''they'' will be Party A and their customers Party B, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can spark an unseemly dispute from which the dealer will inevitably have to back down. At least one swap dealer solved this problem by deciding to be “Party B” as standard. This only confused clients who were unused to being “Party A”.  
This has led to two kinds of bother: first, a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since [[swap dealer]]s set up their templates to assume ''they'' will be Party A and their customers Party B, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can spark an unseemly dispute from which the dealer will inevitably have to back down. At least one swap dealer solved this problem by deciding to be “Party B” as standard. This only confused clients who were unused to being “Party A”.  
Line 43: Line 45:
Furthermore, when labouring over some neatly [[iatrogenic]] [[co-calculation agent]] fallback dispute mechanism — and be assured, you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by your reward, in heaven or on earth, for doing so — it is easy to get your “[[Party A]]s” and “[[Party B]]s” mixed up. Doing so buries, deep in the [[fossil record]], a technical deficiency that may go entirely unrecognised for ''decades''.  
Furthermore, when labouring over some neatly [[iatrogenic]] [[co-calculation agent]] fallback dispute mechanism — and be assured, you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by your reward, in heaven or on earth, for doing so — it is easy to get your “[[Party A]]s” and “[[Party B]]s” mixed up. Doing so buries, deep in the [[fossil record]], a technical deficiency that may go entirely unrecognised for ''decades''.  


Roll forward eighteen years. The world is again on the brink of financial [[Apocalypse]]. The customer is now a [[systemically important financial institution|systemically-important]] leviathan, largely thanks to years of optimistically lax credit sanctioning. But suddenly, it is teetering. The [[Credit officer|chief credit officer]] runs about with her hair on fire and for the first time, ''everyone is staring forensically at the docs''. Suddenly that co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism is all that stands between the firm and a three billion dollar abyss. And guess what? ''Some clot transposed Party A and Party B''.
Roll forward eighteen years. The world is again on the brink of financial [[Apocalypse]]. The customer is now a [[systemically important financial institution|systemically-important]] leviathan, largely thanks to years of optimistically lax credit sanctioning. But suddenly, it is teetering. The [[Credit officer|chief credit officer]] runs about with her hair on fire and for the first time, ''everyone is staring forensically at the docs''. Suddenly that co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism is all that stands between the firm and a three billion dollar abyss. And guess what? ''Some clot transposed “Party A” and “Party B”''.


====The real distinction: [[dealer]] and [[customer]]====
====The real distinction: [[dealer]] and [[customer]]====
{{smallcaps|Beyond that small}} class of [[inter-dealer]] swap contracts that make up a dealer’s funding and hedging programme — there ''is'' a material distinction between the parties to an swap contract. The asymmetry comes not from whether one is [[long]] or [[short]], or buyer or seller, but from who is ''customer'' and who is ''dealer''.
{{smallcaps|Beyond that small}} class of [[inter-dealer]] swap contracts that make up a [[dealer]]’s funding and hedging programme — there ''is'' a material distinction between the parties to an swap contract.<ref>Almost all {{isdama}}s will be between a ''customer'' and a ''dealer''. A few will be [[inter-dealer]] — but there are only so many dealers. Almost ''none'' will be inter-customer. I know, I know: the first ever swap was, though, right?</ref> The asymmetry comes not from whether one is [[long]] or [[short]], or buyer or seller, but from who is ''customer'' and who is ''dealer''.


A customer or “[[end user]]” uses the {{isdama}} to ''change'' its absolute exposure to a given risk or underlier. To take, or lay off, a risk.
A customer or “[[end user]]” uses the {{isdama}} to ''change'' its absolute exposure to a given risk or underlier. To take, or lay off, a risk.


A [[dealer]] uses the {{isdama}} to earn a [[commission]]. It does this, yes, by providing its customers a changed absolute exposure, but at the same time carefully hedges that exposure so that, but for those fees, the dealer is market ''flat''. Now, it is the nature of the beast that a dealer can’t always ''stay'' market flat: it is too dependent upon the performance of its customers, counterparties and models for that — but this is not for want of trying. The {{isdama}} is as much a borrower/lender arrangement as most other banking arrangements. See [[a swap as a loan|the JC’s long-form essay]] about this.
A [[dealer]] uses the {{isdama}} to earn a [[commission]]. It does this, yes, by providing its customers a changed absolute exposure, but at the same time carefully hedges that exposure so that, but for those fees, the dealer is market ''flat''. Now, it is the nature of the beast that a dealer can’t always ''stay'' market flat: it is too dependent upon the performance of its customers, counterparties and models for that — but this is not for want of trying.  
 
In any case, almost all {{isdama}}s will be between a ''customer'' and a ''dealer''. A few will be [[inter-dealer]]. Almost ''none'' will be inter-customer.<ref>I know, I know: the first ever swap was, though, right?</ref>


====Why does it matter?====
====Why does it matter?====

Revision as of 09:35, 19 December 2023

Bilateral
/ˌbaɪˈlætᵊrᵊl/ (adj.)
Having, or relating to, two sides; affecting both sides equally.

In this episode the JC considers the “bilateral” nature of the ISDA Master Agreement, why swap participants are called “counterparties” what this confusing “Party A” and “Party B” business is all about.

These labels set the ISDA apart from its fellow finance contracts. They give it a sort of otherworldly aloofness; a sense of social justice. Other banking and broking transactions use labels which help you orient who, in the power structure, is who: a loan has a “Lender” (always the bank) and “Borrower” always the punter. A brokerage has “Broker” (master) and “Customer” (servant).[1]

But not the ISDA Master Agreement. From the outside its framers — the First Men — opted for the more gnomic, interchangeable and equal designatorsParty A” and “Party B”.

Why? Well, we learn it from our first encounter of an ISDA Schedule. Bilaterality.

Bilaterality

A belief in even-handedness gripped the ones whose deep magic forged the runes from which the First Swap was born.

Where most finance contracts imply some sort of dominance and subservience. A large institutional “have” indulges a small commercial “have-not” with debt finance, for which privilege the bank extracts excruciating covenants and enjoys a preferred place in the queue for repayment among the customer’s many scrapping creditors.

But swaps, as the First Men saw them, are not like that.

“A swap contract,” they intoned, “is an exchange among peers. It is an equal-opportunity sort of thing; Biblically righteous in that, under its awnings, one be neither lender nor borrower, but an honest rival for the favour of the Lady Fortune, however capricious may she be.”

“Thus, we are equals. Rivals. Counterparties”.

Covenants, privileges of credit support and so on may, thereby, flow either way. They may flow both ways. In our time of regulatory margin, they usually do.

And, to be sure, swaps are different from loans and brokerage arrangements. They start off “at market”, where all is square. Either party may be long or short, fixed or floating: at the moment the trade is struck, the world infused with glorious possibility.

One fellow’s fortunes may rise or fall relative to the other’s and, as a result, she may owe (in the vernacular, be “out-of-the-money”) or be owed (“in-the-money”). And swaps, too, are professional instruments. Moms and pops, Belgian dentists and the like may take loans and buy bonds, but they don’t, and never have, entered ISDA Master Agreements.[2]

Curiously, the pre-printed ISDA Master Agreement itself never uses the expressions “Party A” or “Party B”. Have a look, if you don’t believe me. Being genuinely bilateral, it never has to. Being arbitrary assignations at trade level, party-specific labels only get a mention once the symmetry breaks down. That happens in the Schedule and in Confirmations, to be clear who is who on a given trade, or for a given bespoke convenant: who pays the fixed rate and who the floating; which thresholds, maxima, minima, covenants, details, agents and terms apply to which counterparty. This much is necessarily different. Nothing beyond: the ISDA Master Agreement assumes you already know who is who, having agreed it in the Schedule.

So we agree: for this swap trading relationship we will call you “Party B”, and me “Party A”. Beyond these colourless labels, we are equal. These generic terms hark from a time where the idea of “find and replace all” in an electronic document seemed like Tipp-Ex-denying, devilish magic.

But anyway. Being so generic, the “Party A” and “Party B” labels still lead to practical difficulties: a dealer with thirty thousand counterparties wants to be “Party A” every time, just for peace of mind and literary continuity when perusing its collection of Schedules, as we know dealers on occasion are minded to do.[3] If, here and there, a dealer must be “Party B”, this can lead to anxious moments should one misread one such Schedule and conclude the carefully-argued infinite IM Threshold applies to the other guy when really, as it ought, it applies to you.

Frights like this are, in their way, quite energising.

“BINO” — bilateral in name only

But there is a better objection: for all our automatic protestations to the contrary, the ISDA is not really a bilateral contract. It is often a financing contract, in economic effect even if not in formal structure. Where one side is a customer gaining exposure to a market risk and the other wise is a dealer providing delta-hedged exposure to that risk, a swap is a sort of “synthetic loan”.

This thought grew and grew and now there is a whole new article about it.

But except for that a class of inter-dealer swap relationships, ISDA Master Agreements are “bilateral” only really in name: one party — the swap dealer, provides exposures to another, the customer, who consumes them. The customer provides the impulse to trade; the customer elects when to exercise options and terminate positions. The dealer hedges, calculates values and is burdened with additional regulatory capital charges if it doesn’t get its close-out netting right. The customer punts.

This has led to two kinds of bother: first, a bit of a squabble as to who gets to be Party A and who Party B; since swap dealers set up their templates to assume they will be Party A and their customers Party B, when immovable object meets irresistible force it can spark an unseemly dispute from which the dealer will inevitably have to back down. At least one swap dealer solved this problem by deciding to be “Party B” as standard. This only confused clients who were unused to being “Party A”.

Furthermore, when labouring over some neatly iatrogenic co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism — and be assured, you will spend far more time doing this than can ever be justified by your reward, in heaven or on earth, for doing so — it is easy to get your “Party As” and “Party Bs” mixed up. Doing so buries, deep in the fossil record, a technical deficiency that may go entirely unrecognised for decades.

Roll forward eighteen years. The world is again on the brink of financial Apocalypse. The customer is now a systemically-important leviathan, largely thanks to years of optimistically lax credit sanctioning. But suddenly, it is teetering. The chief credit officer runs about with her hair on fire and for the first time, everyone is staring forensically at the docs. Suddenly that co-calculation agent fallback dispute mechanism is all that stands between the firm and a three billion dollar abyss. And guess what? Some clot transposed “Party A” and “Party B”.

The real distinction: dealer and customer

Beyond that small class of inter-dealer swap contracts that make up a dealer’s funding and hedging programme — there is a material distinction between the parties to an swap contract.[4] The asymmetry comes not from whether one is long or short, or buyer or seller, but from who is customer and who is dealer.

A customer or “end user” uses the ISDA Master Agreement to change its absolute exposure to a given risk or underlier. To take, or lay off, a risk.

A dealer uses the ISDA Master Agreement to earn a commission. It does this, yes, by providing its customers a changed absolute exposure, but at the same time carefully hedges that exposure so that, but for those fees, the dealer is market flat. Now, it is the nature of the beast that a dealer can’t always stay market flat: it is too dependent upon the performance of its customers, counterparties and models for that — but this is not for want of trying.

Why does it matter?

What is in a name?

This may be to draw a long bow, but you could argue that emphasising bilaterality has led the regulatory dance into the wrong corner of the dancefloor. The JC does.

The logic is this: this is a contract of equals. Each poses an equal, but offsetting, risk to the other. Therefore credit concern cuts both ways, so any regulatory impositions should — must — also apply both ways.

And so we have seen: swap dealers have to post regulatory initial and variation margin to their customers, just the same way their customers must post it to them.

But this is nuts. Swap dealers are regulated financial institutions providing a service for a fixed commission. When dealing they don’t take on outright market positions. They must hold regulatory capital against their dealing activity. That this means of managing systemic risk hasn’t always worked fabulously well is not the point: the principle is sensible: ensure financial institutions are sound by obliging them to hold on to money, rather than making them give it away.

And a customer who frets about its outsized exposure to a dealer has a ready solution: move its business away. Diversifying the portfolio encourages competition in the market and introduces a healthy redundancy.[5] Overall, encouraging customers to limit their outright exposure to dealers enhances the market’s overall resilience.

Obliging dealers to cash-collateralise customers’ open positions creates the opposite incentives. Customers are encouraged not to diversify their risk, but to concentrate it, with the dealers offering the most aggressive margin rates. And the dealer market is competitive to the point of being paranoid, as we learned from Archegos. Dealers will cut their required margins to the bone, thereby increasing their risk of loss.

By contrast, end users are not regulated. They are often thinly capitalised funds, trading with leverage on someone else’s money: guess who? The dealer.

The real source of systemic dealer risk, is the second-order risk presented by the dealer’s customers blowing up.

This is a situation a dealer is more likely to get itself into if it has to pay away wodges of regulatory margin to collateralise un-realised customer gains, giving those customers, already betting with the broker’s money, even more of it. We have a separate essay on this: See when variation margin attacks.

Might the market have gravitated this way were it not for our fiction of pretending this is a bilateral relationship?

  1. Okay I know theoretically it is the other way around, but it isn’t, is it? You are hooked up to the great battery grid, just like everyone else. Admit it.
  2. They may trade contracts for difference and make spread bets with brokers, but these are standardised, smaller contracts.
  3. They are not.
  4. Almost all ISDA Master Agreements will be between a customer and a dealer. A few will be inter-dealer — but there are only so many dealers. Almost none will be inter-customer. I know, I know: the first ever swap was, though, right?
  5. In “normal accidents” terminology financial markets are tightly-coupled, non-linear systems where “slack” loosens that coupling and reduces the risk of catastrophic failure.