Term stock loan: Difference between revisions

From The Jolly Contrarian
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{g}}{{a|gmsla}}An unusual type of [[stock loan]] where the {{gmslaprov|Lender}} agrees to a [[fixed term]] during which it cannot call back the {{gmslaprov|loan}} without the {{gmslaprov|Borrower}}’s agreement.
{{g}}{{a|gmsla|'''Term stock loan: Like a normal stock loan, only the usual provisions }}An unusual type of [[stock loan]] where the {{gmslaprov|Lender}} agrees to a [[fixed term]] during which it cannot call back the {{gmslaprov|loan}} without the {{gmslaprov|Borrower}}’s agreement.


This is an unusual arrangement, since generally [[stock loan]]s are meant to cover [[short sale]]s where the Borrower, by definition, doesn't know how long it wants the stock, or when it will want to terminate the loan — [[Short-seller|short-selly]] [[hedge fund]] dude is waiting for the market to tank so {{sex|he}} can buy the borrowed stock back in, settle his loan make a huge profit, right? — and seeing as that is an open-ended arrangement <ref>[[The market can stay irrational longer than you can stay solvent]] as Bill Ackman would ruefully tell you.</ref> a run-of-the-mill [[stock loan]] is [[callable]] at any time.<ref>the Borrower might need its stock back on any day — if it does, short-selly [[hedge fund]] dude can borrow in more from someone else and return that to the original lender, slosing out the first loan. End of the day, he remains short one [[stock loan]].</ref>.
This is an unusual arrangement, since generally [[stock loan]]s are meant to cover [[short sale]]s where the Borrower, by definition, doesn't know how long it wants the stock, or when it will want to terminate the loan — [[Short-seller|short-selly]] [[hedge fund]] dude is waiting for the market to tank so {{sex|he}} can buy the borrowed stock back in, settle his loan make a huge profit, right? — and seeing as that is an open-ended arrangement <ref>[[The market can stay irrational longer than you can stay solvent]] as Bill Ackman would ruefully tell you.</ref> a run-of-the-mill [[stock loan]] is [[callable]] at any time.<ref>the Borrower might need its stock back on any day — if it does, short-selly [[hedge fund]] dude can borrow in more from someone else and return that to the original lender, slosing out the first loan. End of the day, he remains short one [[stock loan]].</ref>.

Revision as of 16:16, 19 June 2019

The Jolly Contrarian’s Glossary
The snippy guide to financial services lingo.™
Index — Click the ᐅ to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.
GMSLA Anatomy™

Term stock loan: Like a normal stock loan, only the usual provisions

2010 GMSLA: Full wikitext · Nutshell wikitext | GMLSA legal code | GMSLA Netting

Pledge GMSLA: Hard copy (ISLA) · Full wikitext · Nutshell wikitext |
1995 OSLA: OSLA wikitext | OSLA in a nutshell | GMSLA/PGMSLA/OSLA clause comparison table
From Our Friends On The Internet: Guide to equity finance | ISLA’s guide to securities lending for regulators and policy makers

Navigation
2010 GMSLA 1 · 2 · 3 · 4 · 5 · 6 · 7 · 8 · 9 · 10 · 11 · 12 · 13 · 14 · 15 · 16 · 17 · 18 · 19 · 20 · 21 · 22 · 23 · 24 · 25 · 26 · 27 · Schedule · Agency Annex · Addendum for Pooled Principal Agency Loans

2018 Pledge GMSLA 1 · 2 · 3 · 4 · 5 · 6 · 7 · 8 · 9 · 10 · 11 · 12 · 13 · 14 · 15 · 16 · 17 · 18 · 19 · 20 · 21 · 22 · 23 · 24 · 25 · 26 · 27 · 28 · Schedule · Agency Annex

Stock lending agreement comparison: Includes navigation for the 2000 GMSLA and the 1995 OSLA

Index: Click to expand:
Tell me more
Sign up for our newsletter — or just get in touch: for ½ a weekly 🍺 you get to consult JC. Ask about it here.

An unusual type of stock loan where the Lender agrees to a fixed term during which it cannot call back the loan without the Borrower’s agreement.

This is an unusual arrangement, since generally stock loans are meant to cover short sales where the Borrower, by definition, doesn't know how long it wants the stock, or when it will want to terminate the loan — short-selly hedge fund dude is waiting for the market to tank so he can buy the borrowed stock back in, settle his loan make a huge profit, right? — and seeing as that is an open-ended arrangement [1] a run-of-the-mill stock loan is callable at any time.[2].

The one use case for a term stock loan is for your prime broker. Here is a fellow who has financed a lot of crappy securities that are now cludging up her balance sheet. She wants to covert them into high quality assets that his Treasury department will accept in reduction of overall financing costs. This she will do by “upgrading” them with an agent lender. she borrows, say, US treasuries, collateralises those with equities, and gives the treasuries to her treasury department who will give her funding credits against her margin loans. It will help with our PB’s LRD calculations if she can say those US treasury Loans have a certain minimum term: three months is common.


There is no cross default in a securities financing transaction

There’s no need for cross default in any master trading agreement, actually — this is the JC’s considered view, about which you can read at length elsewhere — but the 2010 GMSLA and Global Master Repurchase Agreement are a particularly bad candidates for cross default because their transactions are by definition short term (in the case of repo) and callable at any time (in the case of stock loans) and fully collateralised, so the “mischief” cross default is designed to fix — large credit exposure under long tenor transactions with few regular cash-flows — does not exist.

Remember that:

  • Large credit exposure
  • Long term exposure with no break rights
  • Infrequent cashflows

Cross default is designed for transactions with all of these features. A standard SFT has none of these features.

Cross default is a banking concept. It is designed to protect lenders who have unsecured credit exposure to borrowers under fixed rate loans where the only payments will be period interest payments, which might be only quarterly, half-yearly or even yearly. For your average credit officer, a year between scheduled payments is a long time between drinks. If she knows the borrower has defaulted in a big way to some other lender — some randomshe will not want to wait nine months to for a failure to pay on her own facility. She will want to hit DEFCON 5 straight away; ideally, even before that other random lender has.

Hence, she will seek a cross default right: If random guy can pull you down, I can pull you down.

There’s no need to put one in. Even if you are doing term loans.

All the talk of borrowers and lenders in securities financing transactions makes a fellow giddy. But remember: SFTs are not contracts of indebtedness. Even though they’re calledLoans”, they are not actually, you know, loans. Lenders aren’t — legally or economically —lenders[3]. Thus, there is no cross default in any standard SFT agreements. This was not a mistake. It was deliberate. You don’t need one.

Now, there is a certain stripe of credit officer who will not be convinced of this, and will want to put one in anyway. Does it do any harm? Well yes, actually: it creates contingent liquidity issues for your own treasury department, whom credit will routinely ignore when making their credit requests. And yes, from the perspective of production waste in the negotiation process: insisting on a cross default is, par excellence, the waste of over-processing.

Yeah, but why not, just to be on the safe side?

Why not put one in for good measure? SFTRs are collateralised daily, so:

  • Neither party has material exposure[4];
  • There will usually be payments flowing each way daily as loaned Securities and Collateral values move around, creating collateral transfers; and
  • Even if there aren’t, either party can recall the loans on any day[5]

Ok, how about set-off. I’ve got you there, haven’t I?

With set-off you truly open yourself up to the risk of a negotiation oubliette.

In any weather, set-off is a furry and misunderstood thing. Consider two scenarios: one where you have independent, live close-out rights under different master agreements (i.e., you don’t actually need a Cross Default), but no written contractual right of set-off between those agreements, and one where you do not: Your 2010 GMSLA has blown up, but your counterparty doggedly hangs on under your other master agreements like Harold Lloyd dangling from a clock tower, refusing to let go, heroically continuing to perform, defying the circling vultures of default.

Double default, no contractual set-off

Where both master agreements have independently terminated, you have a common-law set-off right.[6] It might not quite ameliorate your financial reporting team’s regulatory capital calculators, but you would need a fully weaponised master netting agreement and separate netting opinion to help with that anyway.

But, in practice you have off-setting obligations, in the same currency, due immediately (and therefore onthe same day) and under common law there is a set-off right. This may be interfered with by your counterparty’s insolvency — but then so would an explicit set-off clause, unless you had a F.W.M.N.A. as described above — but in many cases would not: In English law, for example, insolvency set-off is not just available but compulsory.

This is to do no more than recognise that possession is nine-tenths of the law: I may owe you fifteen, but you owe me ten, so I will paying five and we will be square. Since no insolvency regime sophisticated enough to contemplate post-insolvency set-off would deny its efficacy, we must assume the law will be silent, and it will be a resourceful insolvency practitioner indeed who can construct an equitable argument to overcome that. (If you owe me twenty I will be a sport and call it quits if you pay me five: until that time you can whistle for it).

Single default, no contractual set-off

Where only one master agreement has actually defaulted — the Harold Lloyd scenario — it is even easier. By your own theory of the game, your counterparty, though broken, battered, bruised and perhaps expiring in a heap behind the dumpsters in the alley next to the kitchen, is still with us. Here we are contemplating an arrangement rather like “settlement netting”. I owe you, you owe me, and I am simply going to serially discharge you from your indebtedness to me by neglecting to pay you, and declaring that inaction a satisfaction of your corresponding debt to me. If it would be hard for an insolvency practitioner to argue against that kind of practical withholding, imagine how hard it will be for a solvent counterparty. Especially one on the bones of it arse, that can’t afford a decent lawyer. If if could, it would have just paid you in the first place, right?

No doubt purists will rail that this is a grubby, speckled and imperfect analysis. It is not true in all worlds, for all times, and it snubs its snotty nose at the proprieties of modern financial services legal practice. It is not accompanied by opinions. It is a bit too visceral; a bit too swooned by the earthy appeal of the mundane and every-day; it doesn’t acknowledge the primacy of the legal music of the spheres to which the philosopher kings of our industry like to tap their feet.

Guilty as charged: The JC’s philopsher king is Voltaire, and those who seek the perfect will still be formulating their close-out notices and preparing statements of claim, while we pragmatic folk have settled up caught a cab.

  1. The market can stay irrational longer than you can stay solvent as Bill Ackman would ruefully tell you.
  2. the Borrower might need its stock back on any day — if it does, short-selly hedge fund dude can borrow in more from someone else and return that to the original lender, slosing out the first loan. End of the day, he remains short one stock loan.
  3. If anything, a fully collateralised Lender, benefitting from a 5-10% haircut, is a net borrower. See Pledge GMSLA for what do about that if upsets your leverage ratio denominator.
  4. Okay, okay, a borrower under an agent lending transaction may have a significant exposure across all lenders due to aggregated collateral haircuts, but that is by definition diversified risk, and the borrower can generally break term transactions.
  5. Unless they are term transactions, but even there, the terms tend to be short — ninety days is a maximum — and see above re usual daily collateral flows.
  6. assuming your base currency is the same for each. If it is not I CAN’T HELP YOU. YOU ARE MEANT TO BE A PROFESSIONAL.